Compensating for Waiting Time Failures

Submission to the Select Committee on Health In Regard to the Injury Prevention, Rehabilitation, and Compensation Amendment Bill (2004, No 3) by Brian Easton and Alan Gray.

Keywords: Health; Social Policy;

Summary of Submission

We support the general approach of the Bill to remove the notion of fault in medical misadventure and to extend rehabilitation and compensation to all those who suffer treatment injury. However, we do not believe there should be any exemption for treatment injury as a result of resource shortages. This is inconsistent with the Bill’s general principles.We recommend that the Bill be amended by deleting the proposed new Section 32,(2c), thus making it absolutely clear that in principle all treatment injury is covered by the ACC medical misadventure scheme, whatever the cause.We recommend that the Government immediately institute a Waiting Times Strategy to eliminate, over a period of not more than three years, excess waiting times.

We recommend that a procedure be devised that where treatment injury is caused by resource shortage, that a review process be established parallel to that which applies to health professionals.

1. General Issues: Support for the Legislation

1.1. We wish to support the general approach of the “Injury Prevention, Rehabilitation, and Compensation Amendment Bill (No 3)” which proposes to eliminate the fault element in regard to Medical Misadventure, and replace it with an entitlement based on Treatment Injury.

1. 2. The fault principle has no place in the rest of the ACC legislation, for the reason that it has no place in medical misadventure. It impedes rehabilitation, it delays fair compensation, and it discourages the development of the safety culture which should be aiming to prevent further misadventures. The submission of one of us to the earlier committee of enquiry whose recommendations led to the Bill under consideration is attached as Appendix A. (Also attached as Appendix B is a Listener column which one of us wrote.)

1.3. We are satisfied that the alternative proposals for dealing with medical professionals who display incompetence via the Health and Disability Commissioner and their professional bodies will be effective, and will not have the deleterious impact on prevention, rehabilitation and compensation that the current system generates.

1.4. We are delighted that ACC is establish a unit to use the information that will be generated by the new scheme to develop a safety culture and increase prevention. Whether such a responsibility should be included specifically in the legislation is a matter of public policy. Whether there should be unit with such a remit somewhere in the government system is a matter of principle.

1.5 We support the general approach of the Bill to remove the notion of fault in medical misadventure and to extend rehabilitation and compensation to all those who suffer treatment injury. However. we do not believe there should be any exemption for treatment injury as a result of resource shortages. This is inconsistent with the Bill’s general principles. Our objection is detailed in the next section.

2. The Resource Shortage Exemption

2.1 Section 13 of the Bill proposes to amend the principal Act by repealing sections 32 to 34, and substituting revised sections consistent with the new principles.

2.2 However the new section 32, “Personal injury caused by treatment (treatment injury)”, has a provision as follows:

(2) Personal injury caused by treatment or treatment injury does not include the following kinds of personal injury: …
(c) personal injury that is solely attributable to a resource allocation decision:

2.3 We take the view, which we believe is widely held within the professional medical community, that a personal injury arising from failure to treat for whatever reason is a treatment injury. That includes failure to treat because of resource shortages.

2.4 Therefore, we reject the Bill’s notion that the failure to treat because of resource allocation decisions is not treatment injury, even though a failure to treat by a medical professional is treatment injury,

2.5 Indeed, we see the possibility of an appalling anomaly arising, insofar as two patients could have the same condition, and be treated at the same time. One, however, may receive compensation and rehabilitation because he or she had delayed treatment as the result of a diagnostic error by a medical professional, while in the other receives none because she or he was properly diagnosed but treatment was delayed because of resource shortages.

2.6 We believe that the public will also find it unacceptable that while there is an onus on health professionals to provide high quality care, the effect of the clause is to exempt organisations providing health care from a similar standard. We doubt the public would understand the justification for omitting treatment injury because of a lack of resources from the ACC scheme.

2.7 The proposed clause is a successor to one in the current Act. The amending Bill represents a new vision for the ACC scheme as far as medical misadventure is concerned. It would be totally inappropriate to leave in the Bill a fossil from a past age – in effect an exemption for a particular sort of fault.

2.8 We recommend that the Bill be amended by deleting the proposed new Section 32,(2c), thus making it absolutely clear that in principle all treatment injury is covered by the ACC medical misadventure scheme, whatever the cause.

3. Resource Consequences of The Proposed Change

3.1 The proposed change recommended in our paragraph 2.8 primarily affects where there are waiting lists, with the consequence that patients’ waiting times exceed that recommended by good medical practice. In our view waiting lists are not necessarily inappropriate insofar as their function is medical management. What is unacceptable is excessively long waiting times as a result of mismanagement and resource shortages.

3.2 Currently many patients face excessive waiting times and, as a result, suffer discomfort, the need for further treatment, and/or death, which would have been avoided by treatment within the accepted waiting times. As far was we know ,there is no comprehensive census of the degree of backlog, but there is sufficient fragmentary evidence to indicate many patients suffer from excessive waiting times.

3.3 There are two possible broad strategies for dealing with the abandoning of the exemption for resource shortages.

3.4 The first is that the revised clause come into operation immediately with the enactment of the Bill, and that patients who experience treatment injury from excessive waiting times be dealt with by ACC in exactly the same way as those who experience treatment injury from delayed diagnosis. That option would be our preference.

3.5 However, we are aware that size of the resulting fiscal exposure is unclear. An alternative would be to include in the Bill a specific provision which maintains the principle that treatment injury arises from resource shortage, but which delays the implementation of the principle for a fixed time specified by Parliament. This follows the common practice of different parts of a Bill coming into law at different times. In our view any delay should not be more than three years although, as we have said in our section 3.4, we would prefer immediate implementation.

3.6 Irrespective of whether the strategy of our paragraph 3.4 or of our paragraph 3.5 is adopted, it will be necessary to institute a Waiting Times Strategy, the purpose of which will be to eliminate the waiting time backlogs. A letter written to various people outlining a possible Waiting Times Strategy is attached as Appendix C. We believe that such a strategy is feasible within existing fiscal parameters.

3.7 The Waiting Times Strategy is essentially that each year the Government sets aside an amount from the additional fiscal surplus, and that District Health Boards and other public agencies be invited to tender for a share of it, using the funds to reduce waiting times for particular treatments. Once the backlog had been cleared the Board would promise to maintain their waiting times within the standard set by the Ministry of Health in consultation with relevant medical professionals. We think that a modest amount – we suggested $60m a year – would eliminate excessive waiting times in a short period.

3.8 One of us examined the dynamics of waiting times, and came to the spectacular, albeit it with hindsight obvious, conclusion that elimination of excessive waiting times benefits more than those in the backlog. While the elimination is a one-off outlay, all the subsequent recipients of the treatment within the recognised waiting times also benefit. The paper attached as Appendix D gives two examples based on the effect of delaying radiotherapy treatment for breast cancer using available best estimates of the higher morbidity as a result of delay.
– one shows that eliminating a backlog of 100 would save 22 lives in the first year and 110 in the first five years;
– the second uses a benefit cost analysis framework to conclude that total impact on all the women who would benefit as a result of eliminating a backlog makes the treatment 40 plus more times beneficial than the benefit to the cohort of the backlog.
The implication in either case is that the elimination of excess waiting times must be one of the treatment practices with the highest returns available in the health system.

3.9 We recommend that the Government immediately institute a Waiting Times Strategy to eliminate, over a period of not more than three years, excess waiting times.

4. Organisational Consequences of the Proposed Change

4.1 Currently organisations which fail to provide sufficient resources and so cause treatment injury, are exempt from any review by the proposed provision 32 (2c) and the existing equivalent. Even under the new system there will be no review, even though health professional who make equivalent mistakes are subject to review via the Health and Disability Commissioner and their professional bodies.

The following were attached:
Submission by Brian Easton to the Review of Medical Misadventure
Listener column (17 April 2004) “Accidents Will Happen”
Letter: Waiting Times Strategy
“The Gains From A Reducing Waiting Times” by Brian Easton.

Go to top

Fiscal Foolishness

Imbalanced tax cutting is like pouring petrol on a blazing barbecue

Listener 6 November, 2004.

Keywords: Macroeconomics & Money;

With the general election just a year ahead, I have, as usual, reviewed my approach. My strategy is always to help readers try to understand economic issues, rather than tell them which way to vote. Next year I may have to modify it.

The danger is that some political parties may try to buy votes by promising to reduce the government surplus with more tax cuts and/or higher public spending. That is always a risk, but it has been compounded by the American Right’s support for George Bush’s tax cuts. Because the US dollar is the international reserve currency, the Americans can get away with a big deficit in the short run. But every respected economist believes that the US has embarked on a dangerous course. It will probably weaken the US dollar – and the US economy.

Not only have the American Right, once the keepers of fiscal probity, turned around, but also there is some muddled local thinking. When last year’s government surplus proved higher than expected, Wellington’s Dominion Post demanded further income tax cuts (September 24). It may be too much for its journalists to understand that the measure of the reported surplus, called OBERAC, tells us little about what the government actually has available. (See Stressful Fiscal Sums: Should the Government Spend More and Tax Less?)

But even the office boy knows that, given the current strength of the economy, with strong growth and labour and other shortages, stimulating further spending by tax cuts is foolish – like pouring petrol on a blazing barbecue.

It may seem odd that a Keynesian like myself should be a fiscal conservative. In fact, John Maynard Keynes did not support unlimited government deficits. Keynesianism favoured managing the government fiscal position, favouring a deficit during a depression. But we ain’t in one at the moment.

Although OBERAC is useful for accountants’ concerns, economists use other indicators for evaluating the impact of the government on the economy. A series of deductions is made from it that tends to turn the surplus into a deficit. That is because the government’s savings from its current income (which the OBERAC approximately measures) are used for capital investment (just as your household uses some of its income to buy a car, add to the house, or pay off debt).

Economists have learnt two major lessons since Keynes’s day. First, it is much easier to generate a government deficit than it is to pull it back, easier to cut taxes or increase government spending than the reverse. That is like trying to put toothpaste back in a tube.

Second, the traditional Keynesian analysis implicitly assumed low interest rates, so government interest payments do not compound faster than the economy grows, shifting the burden of taxation to future generations (as Bush has been doing). All very technical, but difficult problems don’t go away because you can’t understand them.

Perhaps I am overreacting. Does anyone take notice of our newspapers? Labour leaders Helen Clark and Michael Cullen are fiscal conservatives. New Zealand First’s Winston Peters and National’s Bill English proved they were when they ran the government finances. National Party Leader Don Brash has not yet had a chance, but as Governor of the Reserve Bank he publicly cautioned against too loose a fiscal stance, warning that interest rates would have to rise if the government did not show restraint. That’s right. Pour petrol on the fiscal barbecue and the Reserve Bank fire brigade will dowse a lot of party guests.

The danger remains that, inflamed by uninformed journalists and desperate to win votes, some parties will promise policies that wreck the fiscal stance. This column will not criticise any party that maintains the current fiscal track but proposes tax cuts offset by public expenditure cuts (or the opposite). And there is room in the future for modest tax cuts or extra public spending as the economy grows. But I promise to criticise vigorously if any significant political party is so irresponsible that its policies compromise the government budget and the sustainable economy. I hope I shan’t have to.

The Land-rover That Time Forgot (review)

The Trekka Dynasty, by Todd Niall (Iconic Publishing, $29.95)

Listener 6 November, 2004.

Keywords: Business & Finance; Political Economy & History;

Making the boxy Trekka the centre of New Zealand’s contribution to the 2003 Venice Biennale bemused New Zealanders, as well as those who visited. Apparently artist Michael Stevenson saw it as a story about a small nation building an industrial economy, to be swept away by 1984. An easy image perhaps, but a superficial one.

The Trekka Dynasty, by Todd Niall, business editor of Radio New Zealand, tells the story of the Trekka, a sort of impoverished Land-Rover. The story begins with the arrival of Arthur Turner and Cissie and her children in the early 1920s. At the centre is son Noel Turner, who certainly should appear in the next volume of The Dictionary of New Zealand Biography. With others of his family, including his stepfather, he developed a motor business, initially based on importing Bradford vans, Jowett cars, and then Volkswagens and Skodas, whose production was typically finished off in New Zealand.

By the 1930s New Zealand could not generate enough foreign exchange from its grass-based export industries to import all it wanted. British preferential arrangements prevented raising tariffs, so the import licences used to conserve foreign exchange were allocated – inevitably crudely – in order to boost employment. Given the widespread demand for cars, a car import licence became a “licence to print money”.

The more local content, the more licences, so the Trekka aimed to maximise the additions. It was based on Skodas supplied cheap because the Czechs were hungry for foreign exchange, too. Given that they supplied the chassis and the engine, it is extravagant to describe the Trekka as a “New Zealand car” – it was a Czech car with New Zealand body and fittings.

In tracing this story, Niall, who describes himself as a “car and motor sport enthusiast”, tells some amusing stories of business progress and business treachery, of Heath Robinson-type production and sales methods, and of bureaucratic interference. (A Labour Department inspector, told that toilet facilities for women staff involved giving a penny from petty cash and using the town hall across the road, insisted on the provision of a female toilet. They sacked the woman worker instead.)

Unfortunately, the enthusiastic Niall lacks the scepticism that is at the heart of good writing. The careful reader will discover that the car’s controls were quirky, that perhaps up to 18 percent of Trekkas were defective, that few were made

(less than 3000) and that the model was extinguished by the Japanese invasion in 1972, well before 1984 (or the last New Zealand assembled car in 1998). The book recounts people’s memories of how industrialisation policy was – but there seems no attempt to go to the official record. What the public sees and remembers is different from the policy process, and since memories are unreliable, there are numerous errors of fact.

The impression is imbalanced. Sure, the motor vehicle industry was once seen throughout the world as the key to industrialisation, but we now know that it was not. Not only was the Trekka a marginal part of New Zealand’s motor vehicle industry, but also the industry was only a marginal part of the manufacturing industry. Better that the Biennale had had a Fisher & Paykel washing machine.

The result is a book that may attract motor enthusiasts, but at best it contributes only anecdotes to issues of industrialisation strategy. The Trekka is an extinct fossil that led nowhere, not even to a kiwi or a tuatara, which, if as clunky, have at least survived millions of years.

Lock into Savings

The retirement debate depends on a disagreement between economists.

Listener : 23 October, 2004.

Keywords: Social Policy;

About 30 years ago economics sharpened its theory of behaviour with the assumption that everyone took economic decisions that gave them the best outcome. We might call this the “neoclassical paradigm”. It simplifies analysis enormously, and was used in policy extensively in the 1980s and 90s. In practice, the paradigm recognises that individuals don’t actually maximise, but it assumes that people are always taking actions that move them closer to the optimum, so the assumption of best outcomes is near enough to be true.

Before we sneer at the paradigm – or giggle at the economist who, failing to solve the equations that said whether you should go to university, implicitly proved that you needed a degree in mathematics to make the decision – we should not forget that the ideological underpinning is that people generally know best for themselves and we should not patronise them.

Even so, observation of individuals shows that people are much more likely to use rules of thumb when making complex decisions. These rules do not always give optimal outcomes, although they usually give good ones. If you are thinking about going to university, the uncertainties of what your courses will teach you, and the future financial and non-financial return they will generate, means that optimal calculations are useless and students usually make guesses. It is such considerations that led to the “behavioural paradigm” challenging the neoclassical one.

Richard Thaler, a pioneer of the behavioural paradigm and a University of Chicago professor, summarises the observed human savings behaviour in the following rules:

(1) Live within your means. Do not borrow to increase consumption except during well-defined emergencies (such as unemployment).
(2) During emergencies, cut consumption as much as possible.
(3) Keep a rainy-day account equal to some fraction of income. Do not raid the account except in emergencies.
(4) Save for retirement in ways that require little self-control.
(5) Borrow only on the security of a real asset.

Sounds plausible? Yet the last rule of thumb conflicts with the student loans scheme, which requires borrowing against an intangible asset. Neoclassical economists say impatiently that it makes sense to borrow against the additional earnings that a university degree may generate. But students know it conflicts with “the rules”, and borrow reluctantly, failing to take courses that are in their best interests. Here we have an example of how behaviour conflicts with the theory that neoclassical economists articulate.

Rule four is especially relevant to our retirement provision debate. The neoclassical theory says that people will save the right amount for their old age. Some economists have tried to demonstrate they do (often using a database that a statistician would think is wholly unreliable). The behavioural theory says they won’t, unless they lock themselves into a savings plan.

In practice we lock ourselves when we buy a house and systematically pay off the mortgage, and – sort of – when we expect the government to look after our New Zealand Superannuation. There are other locked-in arrangements, the largest of which is occupational superannuation where each payday some of the pay is diverted into a long-term savings account. Even so, very few people are in such a scheme, although a good number of retirees now wish they had been.

New Zealand First campaigned in 1996 for a compulsory occupational pension scheme that would top up the government-provided New Zealand Superannuation, and was not unlike the scheme introduced by Labour in 1975 (but repealed by Robert Muldoon in 1976). Somehow the idea got transmuted into the very different 1998 referendum scheme that would have abolished New Zealand Superannuation, albeit in an incredibly clumsy and confused way. Fortunately, we rejected it.

There is now a proposal to resurrect the 1975 Labour-NZF scheme, except it will be voluntary to participate. If implemented, workers will be able to lock themselves into a retirement savings scheme by a deduction from each pay. Rule four makes it sound eminently sensible, especially as it is voluntary. Thaler supports a similar scheme in the US.

Why will anyone join the scheme? Why not procrastinate until next payday? There is a case for joining incentives. Employers may make regular co-payments. Booster payments are allowed: why not lump-sum contributions from the family? “Son [or daughter], you join the scheme and we’ll put in $10,000.” Sweeteners are suggested. I favour deferring income tax on the deposited savings, taxing them when they are withdrawn. An absolute must for young contributors is that they can use their fund in some way for house purchase.

Neoclassical anti-Thalerians will resist such common sense. But it is wiser to inculcate the rules into your children than confine them to a neoclassical economic education.

Globalisation and Economic Sovereignty

Paper to the Wayne University Law School, October 21, 2004. (Revised)

Keywords: Globalisation & Trade;

The Economist’s Meaning of Globalisation

Globalisation (or globalization) is much discussed today, although popular sentiment is, by the standards of scholarly discourse, opinionated, uniformed, and confused. The growing consensus among economic scholars may be summarised as follows:

First, economic globalisation is defined as “the closer integration of national economies”, to which I would add “and regions” because internal integration is so similar to, but preceded, international integration. For instance, it is helpful to think of as the economic integration of the regions of the United States in the nineteenth century as a form of globalisation.

There is an ambiguity in the scholars’ definition. ‘Globalisation’ may refer to the process of globalisation, or it may refer to the degree of globalisation. The distinction can be important, especially when different time periods are compared. In the first half of the twentieth century the process of globalisation was quiescent or even reversed, but there was still a considerable degree of globalisation, that is interdependencies between economies. And if at the time the process was zero or negative, the level of globalisation was still higher than what it had been at the beginning in the first half of the nineteenth (when the process was more vigorous). Moreover, the interdependencies are multi-dimensional, so we see today far greater integration of trade and capital markets than labour markets.

Second, in contrast to the popular discourse, economic scholarship does not see globalisation as a recent phenomenon. A few argue that the process starts as early as the first European explorations in the fifteenth century, but the consensus is that globalisation begins in the early nineteenth century (say 1820). The process of economic globalisation was virtually non-existent in the first half of the twentieth century although, as mentioned, the degree of globalisation was somewhat higher than in the first half of the eighteenth century. There is debate whether the stagnation began in 1914 or up to thirty years earlier, but a general acceptance that it came to an end, and a new phase of globalisation began, shortly after the Second World War, say in 1950.

This pattern is illustrated by that all international trade was 1.0 percent of World GDP rising to 9.0 percent in 1929, but falling to 5.5 percent in 1950. In 1998 it was 17.2 percent, and is no doubt higher today. Other indicators – say of capital and labour flows – have the same general pattern but the timing of the turnarounds differ.

Third – and this is less explicit in the literature – globalisation is a consequence of the falling costs of distance. This is no surprise: national integration occurs when the connections between regions improve; trade based on comparative advantage is going to be negligible when the costs of transporting the goods are high.

There are two important implication here. As long as the costs of distance continue to fall, the process of globalisation will continue and the degree of globalisation increase. Indeed this will continue for a period after costs no longer fall, as it takes time to adjust to the opportunities they present. The implication is that not only will globalisation continue, but there is a sense that it is irresistible as long as it is driven by falling costs of distance. The policy issue is how to respond to the closer integration of nations, not how to prevent it. Despite Marx’s last thesis of Feuerbach we need first to understand it.

As an economist I am involved in the adapting of economic models to better understand the process. In my view many of the necessary formal models already exist, but they have to be applied differently. There is a tendency among economists to ignore the spatial: economies are treated as columns in a tabulation rather than places on a map. Yet globalisation is essentially about the changes to the spacial allocation of economic activity (and its related growth). There is a sense that the economic scholarship on globalisation will integrate space into economic theory more fundamentally than has occurred in the past.

This raises is the nature of the international economic units which economists study, and hence the dividing lines between the units. Most often in the study of globalisation the lines are geographical of boundaries, but as economists Alberto Alesina and Enrico Spoloare remind us in their The Size of Nations, while in the short term the boundaries may be treated as permanent, over the two hundred years of globalisation they are surprisingly fluid. Few boundaries that existed in 1820, other than those determined by sea are still boundaries today.

Even many of the boundaries of 60 years ago have been changed, and in today’s world there are a number of boundaries – or putative boundaries – across which there are, or have been recently (or there is the potentiality of) sites of significant conflicts: Chechnya; Cyprus; Israel-Palestine; Sri Lanka; Tibet; Timor; Ulster. (The troubles in Iraq are compounded by its geographical boundaries were imposed on a diversity of peoples after the First World War.) Less conflictually, but instructively, the development of the European Union has the effect of changing the significance of the internal boundaries of Europe.

The Meaning of Jurisdictional Boundaries

The European Union example leads to the second implication of the reducing costs of distance, and the resulting trade and factor mobility. The jurisdictional meaning of boundaries is changing, even where the there is no geographical dispute. A starting point for the discussion might be the Treaty of Westphalia of 1648 and the world order that evolved from it.

At the core of its governance system was the principles of the state and sovereignty. Statehood involved dividing the world into territorial parcels each of which was ruled by a separate government. The state was sovereign, by which was meant that it exercised comprehensive, supreme, unqualified, and exclusive control over its territory. ‘Comprehensive’ meant that the state had jurisdiction over all the affairs in the country; ‘Supreme’ meant that it recognised no superior authority; ‘Unqualified’ meant that its right to total authority over its territory was treated as sacrosanct by other states; ‘Exclusive’ ruled out joint sovereignty.

Of course the Westphalian order is a historical phenomenon, and it is not hard to see how these principles, including the implicit notion that territories were eternal, have been breeched over the years. However the economist’s concern is, I think, more fundamental. In the modern world economy it may not be practical to exercise sovereignty in the way that was envisaged 350 years ago, for that was a world in which there was little international – between sovereign state – trade. Earlier I mentioned that as late as 1820 only one percent of the world’s output was traded, while today it is nearer 20 percent. Moreover, most of that trade was what an economist calls ‘absolute advantage’, the product could not be easily produced in the country in which it was consumed. Today comparative advantage trade (importing products that could be produced locally) and competitive advantage trade (exporting products very similar to that which are imported) are more important than absolute advantage trade.

To be provocative I sometimes compare international trade to a marriage where one gives up some autonomy in exchange other benefits. Similarly the benefits from international trade are such that a country gives up some sovereignty. Now of course there is the option of one night stands, although instructively most adults want something more permanent in their lives, and today most trading relationships tend to be based more on an ongoing rather than one-off basis. There may serial monogamy.

Where the parallel with marriage breaks down is that trade is multilateral. Most countries have substantial ongoing trading relationships with a number of partners – smaller economies sometimes seems to be in a harem.. This is even more compromising to sovereignty.

The Institutional Underpinning of Economic Activity

Efficient economic activity requires a set of institutional underpinnings. Typically in a modern state that includes laws which cover a multitude of facets of economic transactions, and the legal institutions to enforce them.

These particular underpinnings were not always there. Personal knowledge of the customer backed by custom and tradition were usually sufficient when trade occurred in a locality. With the falling cost of distance, the geographic range of trade increased, increasingly involving people who did not know one another well or at all. Trust-based institutions could no longer relied upon and it became necessary to impose a law-based underpinning. Moreover, as the costs of distance fell, the central government’s practical reach increased. It is no accident that the end of the nineteenth century saw the evolution of nation-states with increasing ranges of effective economic and commercial intervention across the territory.

The details of the development of the nation-state need not concern us here, but the extending of regulatory power within territories a century or so ago, is parallelled today by a similar worldwide extension, for that is what such institutions as the IMF and the WTO are about. Before looking at such multilateral arrangements it is worth considering the first step of bilateral equivalents, that is between two nations.

Just as there a gains from having a common regulatory framework within a nation there may be gains from aligning the frameworks between trading states. For instance, in the early 1970s New Zealand converted from imperial to metric measures – at some resource expense and discomfort to the public who had to learn a new system – because it would facilitate international trade. There is a potential problem here. Suppose New Zealand were to trade with only two nations which used different measurement conventions. What would New Zealand do?

As it happens, 80 percent of New Zealand’s exports go to country’s that use the metric system, so the answer was simple, once the acknowledgement of the importance of exports to New Zealand – about a third of output is exported. Larger countries have greater choice. The United States retains its own measurement system. Even so, one suspects most of its exports are metric, even if it imports are in American standard measures.

Notice how a problem which began as a bilateral issue – what measurement system should two countries between them use? – became multilateral – what should be the measurement system for the world? It is this point that the marriage analogy breaks down: international economic intercourse is promiscuous.

The multilateral agreements create a rule of law in international commerce, with benefits similar to national commerce from national rule of law. The advantages of a multilateral rule of law over a plethora of bilateral arrangements need hardly be listed. However the benefits of a settlement between two nations in dispute providing guidance to the remaining hundred plus nations should not go unmentioned.

Dejure and Defacto Sovereignty

Even so, multilateralism generates problems for a small country. Consider the aborted Multilateral Agreement on Investment (MAI). The logic was that cross-border investment would benefit from a set of rules, so that foreign investors would know exactly what was expected of them, if they were to invest in any country. Currently this is carried out on a country by country basis which must be exhausting and confusing for the multi-country investor. Why not have a common set of rules? Hence the proposed MAI.

The illustration I am using is hypothetical because the MAI proved unacceptable. In part it had been conceived by nations from the OECD, typically the net investors, who attempted to impose on the world an agreement designed for investor needs without consulting the net debtors. As it happens, the debtor countries dissented and the OECD discovered there was not quite the internal consensus they had assumed. (There were also some problems with the scope of the agreement to which I turn shortly.)

The point I want to make here, is that had some sort of MAI been agreed to by sufficient countries, New Zealand would have been in an invidious position, since almost certainly some provisions could have been unacceptable to it. Should it have assented to such an agreement or should it have rejected it?

A major factor in the public policy debate – but probably not in the public debate, because it may have been too complex and subtle – would have been how to evaluate the benefits of being in a bad agreement against the detriments of not being in it. To progress the illustration I shall accept the public policy framework that international investment is a good thing – although some of those who rejected the MAI do not think so.

The policy framework faces the following unpalatable choice. If New Zealand had stayed out of the MAI (despite just about everyone else agreeing to it) investors would observe that they were not as well covered by New Zealand (or that New Zealand’s parallel provisions were less well understood) and hence were less likely to invest in New Zealand (than they would if there was no MAI). On the other hand if New Zealand acceded to the MAI it would get the foreign investment, but it would also be subject to the downsides of the agreement.

This has all been hypothetical, although the general problem occurs in regard to many other international economic agreements and New Zealand has had to make difficult judgements, even when there are intermediate options such as agreeing to only some provisions, or agreeing with reservations.

But the illustration is enough to make the point that while New Zealand was exercising the de jure sovereignty set out in the Treaty of Westphalia, in fact it had much less choice. It is not just that using its supreme sovereignty New Zealand has agreed to international treaties – economic ones but also others: human rights ones for instance – which limit the supremacy of New Zealand government since supra-national laws and other institutions may over-rule it. In some cases New Zealand felt it had little option but to agree to an international treaty because it thought it better to be in the tent than out. But sometimes it may have preferred there was no treaty or a totally different one.

A case which is facing New Zealand at the moment may be the recently concluded free trade agreement between Australia and the US. (AUSFTA) Australia is New Zealand’s single largest export destination taking around 20 percent of total exports, although for some businesses and industries it is a far more important market. The investment links between the two countries are also substantial. All this is encapsulated in the ‘Closer Economic Relations’ (CER) agreement, which is an ongoing commitment to improve the integration between the two economies.

Inevitably, New Zealand will suffer as a result of AUSFTA because of the standard trade and investment diversion effects that limited free trade agreements generate. In the future, Americans are more likely to source from Australia than New Zealand than they did in the past, and they are also more likely to invest in Australia.

As a consequence, and in some quarters reluctantly, New Zealand sees itself having to negotiate a parallel free trade agreement with the US, to offset the diversion effects of AUSFTA. The reluctance arises because for various reasons a partial free trade agreement may not in itself be beneficial to New Zealand. (One IMF study concluded that an earlier version of AUSFTA may not be beneficial to Australia. There is nothing in economics which says free trade agreements are necessarily beneficial to those involved.)

Thus a small country like New Zealand finds itself in a world where its de facto sovereignty is compromised. It would be possible to revoke New Zealand’s agreement to the treaties it has signed – even those which have no such provision – and in that sense it retains de jure sovereignty. But thus far it has not, and is unlikely to do so, particularly since the revocation of one agreement – except on carefully argued and specifically relevant grounds – would undermine the international community’s trust in the country.

Now one might sat this limiting of de facto sovereignty on economic matters is an inevitable consequence of being small. So let me give an illustration from the largest economy in the world. When it is faced with a challenge under the rules established by the World Trade Organisation, the United States has a policy of vigorously taking a matter to the highest court in the disputes process and then accepting the final decision.

For instance in 1999 the US placed a tariff of at least 9 percent and up to 40 percent on New Zealand’s lamb exports despite an earlier agreement that the tariff was bound to (could not be higher than) only a few cents per kilo. The surcharge was entirely for domestic political purposes, but it may have cost New Zealand farmers up to $NZ45m over three years. New Zealand’s redress was to follow World Trade Organisation procedures. At each stage the WTO found in its favour. Having lost in the final court, the US, having stated it was bound by international trading rules, reduced the tariffs to the bound levels.

This case is not unique but rather reflects a fundamental strategy of the US. In effect it accepts there is a higher decision-making authority than the US. Why does it do so? In fact the US loses some, and it wins some,. (Its score recently was 23 wins and 23 losses.) So while some of its economic interests directly suffer, others directly benefit. But in a wider context, all benefit because they operate their international trading relationships under a rule of law.

The situation is all the more intriguing, because the US does not subject itself to the same discipline in all its non-economic affairs. The most recent spectacular example is that it invaded Iraq without the equivalent of the multilateral agreement which underpins economic relations.

An international rule of economic law makes sense for those economies involved in international trade. Of course the establishment of the regulations tends to favour the powerful. Among the dissenters against the Doha outcomes were those who thought it did not give poor countries enough., but it was designed for the interests of the rich countries.

The cynic might say, she is not surprised – and note that most poor countries will, nevertheless, be made (only slightly?) better off by the implementation of the round. She will recall the parallel in the history of the domestic development of the rule of law. The powerful made laws to suit their own interests but over time the laws came to be extended to suit a wider group of people. (A nice example is that language fossil of ‘judged by one’s peers’. When the barons wrote that principle into the Magna Carta they did not have in mind that it would apply to their serfs – they meant literally that peers of the realm should be judged by peers of the realm and not by the king.)

The Rule of Law Across Boundaries

Even so there is an issue of what should the rule of international economic law cover. We have seen it reduces some sovereignty, but just how much sovereignty should it reduce? A partial answer has a good concept with an ugly name. ‘Subsidiarity’ is the principle that decisions should always be taken at the lowest practical level in the hierarchy. It is now a central principle of the European Union, so that Brussels may not make decisions which can be left to the individual member states, just as the German Federal Republic devolves political power to its constituent Lander (states).

Subsidiarity has a crucial role in the proliferating international agreements of the globalising world, maintaining that multilateral agreements should only cover that which is absolutely necessary, so maximizing national autonomy. The principle is not explicitly a part of the international negotiations, but it is there implicitly.

Unfortunately the application of the principle is vague. Is not leaving a local industry to supply the domestic market an example of subsidiarity? Were it applied, the entire system of world trade would fall apart.

An alternative approach might be define a principle as to those economic decisions which may be left to the nation-state. One possibility might be that international economic rules only apply to commercial transactions – that is voluntary market decisions. But where there is a non-market element than the state can be left to regulate them independently of international law. I shall give a couple of examples shortly, but the principle rests upon the notion that non-market regulation involves intervention by the state, fundamentally different from that provide by the rule of law which underpins commercial transactions.

Unfortunately there is some disagreement as to the line between commercial and non-commercial economic activity, not only along an ideological spectrum but between countries. This was evident in the MAI negotiations. Rich countries intensively regulate their health service sectors on the basis that the conventional market regulation is insufficient given various peculiarities of health care. For many, most evidently Europeans, that regulation covers supply-side regulation, including modes of ownership of core health providers. Essentially their view is health care provision is a non-commercial activity, with some commercial elements. For others – the US is an extreme example – there is much less supply-side regulation, and more private ownership of providers. Conversely their philosophy is of commercial provision withe non-commercial elements. The MAI could not resolve whether private health providers – say American hospitals – must be allowed to compete where the regime is public provider dominated.

If health may be a very difficult area for a economists, the provision of culture is more so. Many rich countries restrict ownership of the broadcasting media, and also sometimes of film making. Opportunities for foreign investment were contentious in the MAI, again reflecting differences in philosophy between commercial and non-commercial provision.

Thus, while suggestive, both the subsidiarity principle and the non-commercial principle, seem deficient in determining the extent to which jurisdictional boundaries may be over-ruled.

Bondaries and Population movements

There is one principle, however, where the boundaries remain intact, although – and intriguingly – that was not so true in the first century of globalisation. Nation-states generally claim the sovereign right to determine who may cross their boundaries. Population mobility is greatly restricted compared to trade and capital mobility, and compared to the nineteenth century.

There are some exceptions. Temporary movements for travel, tourism and education are not exceptions, since countries retain the right to determine who may come. The WTO is discussing the question of movement of natural persons for commercial purposes. The likely outcome is some compromise which moderates, but does not undermine, sovereignty. The biggest exception is that in principle the European Union requires full population movement within its boundaries, although there can be some phasing in.

Now the EU differs from the US in that it is a consortium of nation-states, in which individuals hold national passports and other nation-state citizen entitlements, unlike the US where they are derived from the federal government. (There is a proposal for an EU passport, although initially in parallel with the individual country passports.) Again this is a larger topic than can be traversed here. For the purposes of this paper we note that the boundary between nation-states still has an economic role – perhaps a very important one, illustrated by labour mobility’s significance in the nineteenth century and its crucial role in the development of the US economy.

Even so, the jurisdictional boundary as conceived in the Westphalian system is no longer robust. Economically it is not totally porous, even if that appears the ultimate outcome for ordinary trade and capital flows. Whether there will be a systematisation of a post-Westphalian system, rather than an ad hoc evolution to a not entirely coherent system, is unclear, even if we confine the focus to economics and ignore the political, the military and civil rights.

What we may be sure is that insofar as globalisation is about diminishing costs of distance, the meaning of location is changing, and a superstructure of notions founded on its base are changing– perhaps out of recognition. A crucial part of the superstructure has been governance based on some notion of sovereignty of the nation-state.

Go to top

Fa’a Samoa: Is the Future Of Samoa in New Zealand?

Listener: 9 October, 2004.

Keywords: Globalisation & Trade;

From “Sunset Beach” near the village of Falealupo, the most western part of the Samoan island of Savaii, one looks across the international dateline to tomorrow. Beyond it is New Zealand, where around 120,000 Samoans live – half of all our Pacific Islanders. Auckland is the largest Samoan city – should one say “congregation”? – in the world. Are we Samoa’s future?

It is more complicated than that. Colonial competition divided the islands of Samoa between what is now an independent state of (Western) Samoa, with about 180,000 people, and, to the east, American Samoa, with about 60,000. They look north to Samoan settlements in Hawaii and California, but there is also a constant interchange of people and products between the two jurisdictions.

New Zealand Samoans, although poorer than average New Zealanders, have a material standard of living about double the level of Samoans in Samoa. Even so, the homelanders are literate, with a life expectancy of 70 years. On the UN Human Development Index, they came 70th out of 173 countries in 2001. They appear no less happy than New Zealanders, but have less opportunity there to be, say, a professor of English or to play international sport. Some migration is inevitable, but that is also true for some New Zealanders.

What strikes conventional economics is the vulnerability of the economy to external shocks, despite the Samoan Government’s careful fiscal management and modest external debt. As in most places, production and incomes are underpinned by imports. In 2003, Samoa’s total foreign currency outlays for merchandise and services amounted to 475m tala (about $280m), but exports earned only 280m tala ($165m). Almost three-fifths of that revenue comes from tourist receipts, which makes the economy very exposed to fluctuations in the world tourist market. (It is also exposed to cyclones and global warming.)

The gap between imports and exports is mainly covered by 160m tala ($95m) of remittances from overseas Samoans to their families or for churches and schools – almost three times what the country receives in foreign aid. The biggest remittance sources are the US (39 percent) and New Zealand (31 percent). Some of the tourist receipts are the consequence of Samoans visiting their homeland.

In Samoa, Samoans mainly live in villages, near a church, which is also the community centre. (The denominations are diverse.) The families are large – the typical woman has four children, double the New Zealand average. The limits of economic activity mean there is a steady migration of Samoans overseas that reduces population pressures. New Zealand Samoans continue to keep fa’a Samoa – Samoan ways – even though today over half the New Zealand community is born here. Many can still speak Samoan, they are much more religious than the average New Zealander, and they have larger families, too, averaging three children per New Zealand-born Samoan woman. Their remittances and visiting their homelands show that they remain committed to Samoa.

The Samoan diaspora is not unique. Most nations have members outside the national boundaries, including a relatively smaller New Zealand diaspora (less than 15 percent of the local population, compared to about 100 percent for Samoa). Remittances are not the only way a diaspora supports its nation. Irish-Americans were an important source of investment in the Irish economic boom. Overseas New Zealanders assist us in the international transfer of technology.

There is also a challenge for the hosts. How are we to treat our Samoans? Is it to celebrate the diversity they bring to New Zealand life? Do we respect that they are both New Zealanders and Samoans? Given their younger population, their economic contribution will include providing the nurses for our ageing population. Our aid funding the education and health of Samoans is partly an investment in our future. And although there are common interests between the two governments, there are also differences as to the numbers of migrants and who should migrate. Both countries want the skilled professionals, while migrating professionals may not be as committed to sending remittances. Until recently, the diaspora has not been a policy interest. But in a globalising world, we can no longer ignore the issue, nor hide behind platitudes.

A Strategy for Dealing with Excessive Waiting Times

The following is a letter sent to a number of politicians in the health sector by Alan Gray and Brian Easton

Keywords: Health;

The current amendments to the ACC legislation, which were introduced to the House on 2 August 2004, are a real improvement, & seem widely supported.

However, they continue an anomaly which Sue Bradford referred to in her speech on 5 August 2004 in which she stated that the Green Party were supportive of the Bill in general but had some areas of concern which she hoped would be dealt with in the Select Committee process.

In her speech she stated-
There is a proposition within the bill that will exclude from cover personal injury that is solely attributable to a resource allocation decision. To give one example of what this might mean, it could be applied to someone who is denied ACC cover where the recurrence of metastatic cancer that is caused by delays in provision of radiation therapy for primary cancer occurs solely because there are not enough radiation therapists or equipment to carry out the treatment in a timely manner. Unfortunately, this is a very real kind of situation in New Zealand at present and we would like to see the bill amended to remove this exclusion, at least for injuries which are of such severity that they currently qualify as a medical mishap. For example, causing death, hospitalisation for more than 14 days or significant disability for more than 28 days. [Our emphasis].

In fact, section 33[4] of the Injury Prevention, Rehabilitation and Compensation Act states that – “medical error” does not exist solely because desired results are not achieved, subsequent events show that different decisions might have produced better results, or the failure in question consists of a delay or failure attributable to the resource allocation decisions of the organisation .[Our emphasis]

It seems therefore that while health professionals can commit errors, the organisation cannot!

Although the public rhetoric is in terms of ‘waiting lists’, the issue is really the time a person has to wait between the medical decision to treat and the treatment itself.

Waiting times cannot be shortened overnight, but a campaign to shorten the significant ones over a period can be implemented so they at least fall within the waiting times guidelines. What is proposed here is to systematise the process in the following five steps.

1. A Census of Waiting Times. Each hospital should report annually its typical waiting time for each treatment, alongside the guidelines for each type of treatment.

2. An evaluation by clinicians and economists of the social costs of the waiting times. (This is necessary for stage 4).

3. The government should set aside a substantial amount each year, say, $60million (or some fiscally prudent sum), and invite hospitals to tender for amounts to enable it to shorten its waiting times to within the guidelines.

4. The sums allocated would aim to maximise the reduction in social costs.

5. Successful tenderer’s would agree to maintain from their own resources, waiting times to the agreed level thereafter.

What is being proposed here is not very different from the roading strategy, where the government is finding additional funds to catch-up for the backlog of congested roads.

Because it is a fixed amount which is tendered for, the fiscal risk is largely confined to the alternate uses the funds could be put to. There is also a minor fiscal risk if those who avoid the waiting lists by purchasing their treatment privately (often with medical insurance) switch back into the public health system.

The political risk would be to do step 1, without thoroughly anchoring it into steps 2-5, so that there is a clamour over the waiting times, but the public does not think anything is getting done.

Waiting times have served their purpose, & every effort should be made to abolish them. The current stricter criteria for acceptance on to the list, & the greater accountability of health professionals in the system, has not been followed by sufficient resources to deal with the problem [Although the variation between hospitals suggest there are major management problems contributing to them as well].

The present ACC amendment bill could serve as a stimulus for the Government to revisit the problem, develop a much more aggressive strategy for dealing with waiting times, & allow ACC to act as a spur to hospital management to improve their performance

Such a bold approach would demonstrate the Government means business in providing an efficient health service.

We would be pleased to discuss this further with you if you wish.

Yours sincerely,

Alan Gray and Brian Easton

A paper, The Gains From Reducing Waiting Times, shows the high value of eliminating excess waiting time backlogs.

The Gains from Reducing Waiting Times

There is an accompanying letter A Strategy for Dealing with Excessive Waiting Times.

Keywords: Health;

This note has a simple purpose: to demonstrate the gains from reducing waiting times are somewhat larger than they might at first seem: an economic evaluation of the benefits reducing waiting times is likely to suggest there are very high returns. Essentially this arises because while a shortening of waiting times may appear superficially to benefit just a few people – the numbers in the backlog which are treated – all the subsequent patients are benefited by the shortening of the waiting times. Thus there is a spectacular multiplier from reducing waiting times which makes the gains for the outlay to reduce the backlog far larger than they at first seem.

Background

To illustrate the principle, we use a paper Does Delay in Starting Treatment Affect the Outcomes of Radiotherapy? A Systematic Review by Jenny Huang, Lisa Barbera, Melissa Brouwers, George Browman, and William J. Mackillop. The abstract is attached as an appendix. It is a systematic review which includes 21 studies involving breast cancer patients

Although the paper also looked at head and neck cancer, this illustration focuses on radiotherapy and breast cancer. Pooling a large number of studies the meta-study compellingly shows show that the local recurrence rate (LRR) is higher if the patient receives treatment in 9 to 16 weeks compared to receiving treatment in the first 8 weeks. The study provides an estimate of the LRR of those treated in the first 8 weeks of 5.8 percent and those treated in the following eight weeks of 9.2 percent.

The gain is thus 3.4 percent, but at issue is 3.4 percent of what. It might seem that it is 3.4 percent of the backlog which a Waiting Times Strategy treats. In fact it is 3.4 percent of all the women who as a result of the elimination of the backlog are treated early. This, as we show in an example below, in a year is probably going to be 6.5 times the actual backlog, so that the gains in the first year are 6.5 times 3.4 percent of the backlog number, or 22.1 percent. If the backlog is eliminated for 5 years the gains are more than the backlog.

This report does not carry out a complete evaluation, but recurrence has two economic effects. First women are at increased risk of death and a lower quality of life if their primary treatment fails, and second there are additional treatment costs if they have to undergo “salvage” treatment which usually includes mastectomy, if still feasible, and is often accompanied by chemotherapy treatment. Both are reduced by eliminating the backlog.

Given the multiplier effect, it seems likely that the benefits relative to the costs are high.

Illustration

To show how the multiplier works, consider the following simplified scenario.

Suppose every 8 weeks there are 100 women diagnosed as suitable for treatment radiotherapy for their breast cancer.

We have two scenarios. In Scenario A they are treated within the 8 weeks, and in Scenario B they are treated in the 9 to 16 week period.

To simplify let us assume that in Scenario A they are treated in their 8th week and Scenario B in their 16th week. This means that there are 100 women on the waiting list in Scenario A and 200 in Scenario B. Essentially there is a backlog of 100 cases, which force all women to wait longer than the recommended 8 week treatment.

(Implicit in this is the assumption the waiting lists are stable, and not growing, which is reasonable in most cases over a year, although there is some seasonal variation.)

The total recurrences in Scenario A in one year is the total number of women who are recommended for treatment, which is 650 women (52/8 X 100), times the LRR of 5.8 percent or 37.7 on average.

The local recurrences in Scenario B in the year is the total number of women who are recommended for treatment, which is 650 women (52/8 X 100), times the LRR of 9.2 percent or 59.8 on average.

Thus the difference in local recurrences between Scenario A and Scenario B is 22.1.

Now how many additional treatments is it necessary to get from Scenario B to Scenario A? The answer is 100, because once those 100 additional treatments are done the waiting list will reduce from 200 to 100, that is from scenario B to Scenario A, and all the women can be treated within the 8 weeks.

Thus an outlay of 100 treatments gets a reduction of 22.1 recurrences within a year.

The choice of one year is arbitrary. Suppose, as a result of the removal of the backlog, it is possible to maintain the 8 week treatment target for 5 years. In that case treating the backlog of 100 would eliminate 5 time 22.1 = 110.5 recurrences, that is more than the original number of extra treatments.

This is not a magic. The core of the result is the backlog of 100 is putting 3250 women at additional risk over 5 years.

Economic Evaluation

There is not a sufficient data to do a detailed calculation, but some crude modelling was carried out on the effects of delaying treatment for breast cancer. It used a 10 percent p.a. (real) discount rate and the parameters from the meta-study. It still required an estimate of the benefit to cost ratio for the treatment, which not being known was parameterised. The population was assumed to be a steady state as in the above illustration. Other assumptions are conservative.

Even so the conclusions seems to be robust:

– If the treatment is worth doing, it is always better doing it earlier than later.

– Evaluating the treatment in terms of one cohort (of 8 weeks) is misleading. The social benefit of removing a backlog is forty times – and more – more valuable than the benefit to a single cohort. This arises because of the large number of women who benefit from removing the backlog. In effect for each women who is shifted from the backlog, at least another forty women benefit.

(The ratio of population net benefit to cohort net benefit was 43 if the Benefit to Cost Ratio was 1.1 rising to 62 if the benefit-to-cost-ratio was 3.6).

Choose a Scenario: How Are We Going to Respond to the Doha Round Gains?

Listener: 25 September, 2005. This economics column was designed to be set out in three parallel columns. That is not possible in this format. Instead final two columns are interleaved, to give a sense of the intended juxtaposition. The italics is used to indicate the different scenarios.

Keywords: Globalisation & Trade; Macroeconomics & Money;

It seems possible that the New Zealand economy could eventually have a three percent boost as a result of the Doha Round’s elimination of dumping agricultural products into key New Zealand export markets. About a third will come from higher export prices, and two-thirds from the additional production – on and off the farm.

However, with falling tariffs on manufacturing, we will lose general manufacturing export markets to Australia, as the preferences become less valuable and China undercuts us.

In the following scenarios, I assume world and technology trends are mainly benign over the decade, including no major war or disruptive terrorism. An exception is that the oil prices will continue to rise, which will induce alternative fuel sources (such as biofuels). Transport costs will rise, but not greatly. Oil prices could double, so air travel costs would be back to where they were in about 1990, given continuing technological change. Assume that the Kyoto Agreement is not too disruptive. (If it fails, the warming damage comes after the end of these scenarios.)

If the US economy continues to run an unsustainable budget deficit, I assume the world economy will switch steadily across to the euro as the currency of preference.

The key difference between the scenarios is how we spend the windfall, which is likely to phase in from 2007. Both have their attractions, but the message is that the different economic strategies affect our lifestyle. You may have the chance to choose between them in this year’s election.

SCENARIO 1: SPEND IT!
SCENARIO 2: INVEST IT!

In this scenario, we spend the proceeds. We’ve had a hard time, partly through poor economic management, but also bad luck, while the world agricultural protection that depresses our export prices is not our fault. So as the higher agricultural prices come on line, we use the proceeds to boost consumption, by tax cuts and/or additional public spending, on items such as culture and recreation, the environment and health. Public investment in roads is for reducing commuting and recreational travel costs. We stick to safe economic development – what we know we can do well.
Sure, we consume some of the proceeds from the higher agricultural prices, but we increase the investment, transforming the economy. Transport investment is for getting product to market; we pour money into upgrading the workforce skills (somewhat more efficiently than recent years); we increase spending to promote new industries based on new technologies. More firms succeed, but some innovators go bust.

Land-based exports surge, and our China and other East Asia markets grow while the share of Australia, Europe and the US diminishes. (Even so, we bind our economy and politics more closely with Australia.) The shift to a larger service sector continues. The manufacturing sector diminishes, even though farm-based processing increases and, given a little improved access to the barricaded rich markets, we will send them high-valued returns. Tourism may ease back because of the higher airfares and higher exchange rate. Design skills are not a priority.

Australia is not a big enough market for us, so as well as expanding land-based exports to China and the rest of East Asia, we send manufactures and services to the US and Europe. We remain good friends with Australia, but, like cousins, go our different ways.
Land-based exports expand. Manufacturing switches from the general to high-value technologically advanced products, many of which are airfreighted overseas. Even the growing service sector exports, often via broadband as well as tourism. Good ideas generate significant royalties. We are into intra-industry trade, exporting and importing similar things: pharmaceuticals to Europe and pharmaceuticals from Europe; IT to the US and IT from the US; films to Hollywood, films from Hollywood. We put effort into design, branding and servicing customer needs.

Immigration is restricted, because we don’t need the skills they bring, although later we may have to bring in low-skilled Asians to provide for our elderly.
The environment is under greater pressure and we have to make compromises. The immigration intake is high as we seek skills and aim to get a better age structure.

Output will continue to grow at about the rich world average, and we live in the green and pleasant land we have today, which much of the world envies. But some New Zealanders go overseas to lead more exciting lives.

Output grows a little faster than the rich world average. The world envies us for the vigour, innovation, creativity, and excitement of our society.

Not in the original column: The main determinant of the difference between the two scenarios, is whether we allow the real exchange rate to rise, thus facilitating consumption, or we take measures to keep it low, thus facilitating exporting and the required investment. Detailing this belongs to another column, but will be evident from other items on the website.

Abstracts Of Three Proposed Papers on Institutions and Globalisation

These are being offered to various conferences and seminars. In due course the completed papers will be put up on this website.

Keywords: Globalisation & Trade; Political Economy & History;

1. THE INTERNATIONAL FRAMEWORK

Just as nation-states had to evolved a national institutional framework to underpin their economic activities, the world has had to evolve a parallel framework for international economic intercourse. Prominent examples are the IMF and the WTO and their related rules, but there are a host of such organisations. (For instance, the Organisation International de Métrologie Legale (OIML) is a one of a number of institutions which sets common measurements standards for the world.)

This paper explores three issues:
– the growth of such institutions in the development of the nation-state in the nineteenth century and early twentieth century. (A feature of the larger project of which this paper is a part, is the argument that the nation-state is a response to the regionalisation and globalisation of the nineteenth century);
– the evolution of comparable supranational institutions, mainly in the twentieth century as globalisation intensified;
– the extent to which nineteenth century Pax Britannica is different from late twentieth century Pax America.

The topic is too wide to be fully covered in a single conference paper, so it will look at themes, some key or paradigmatic institutions, with some country examples.

******************

2. OPTIONS FOR STATES IN A GLOBALISING WORLD

Many see late twentieth century globalisation as a threat to the nation-state, ignoring that the nation-state was a creation of nineteenth century globalisation, and has been constantly adapting as globalisation has intensified.

This paper explores options for nation states by comparing the options and limitations that three examples face in the current world economy. They are

1. A state of the United States of America which has little economic autonomy and limited political sovereignty as a consequence of the United States constitution, but which has one of the highest material standards of living in the world (irrespective of which of the fifty is exampled).

2. A country in the European Union which has more economic autonomy and political sovereignty than a state of the US, but which has given up much of these in order to benefit from the European Union.

3. A country, such as New Zealand, which does not belong to any ‘globalised’ integrated regional economy as comprehensive as the United States or the European Union, and therefore has, in principle, more economic autonomy and political sovereignty.

(Choosing the US and EU exemplars has not been completed, but they will in principle have economic structures similar to New Zealand.)

Beyond the comparison is three visions of the future globalised world:
– one like the United States in which what were once were nation-states have very limited autonomy;
– one like the European Union in which nation-states have abandoned much autonomy but retain more than a US state, and have an active involvement in the political process, although there are some democratic (people based) institutions;
– one which would be an extension of today’s world in which nation-states retain greater autonomy, especially over migration, but nevertheless are regulated by supranational arrangements, and where democratic institutions have a very small role in world governance.

******************

3. GLOBALISATION AND ECONOMIC SOVEREIGNTY

It becomes clear, after setting out the economist’s broad understanding of globalisation, that there is a tendency to assume that nation-states are fixed through time. This cant be true, since many of them did not exist in 1820 when the globalisation process began and others were colonies. Indeed it can be argued that the nation-state as we know it is a creation of the underlying processes which drove globalisation. Moreover, boundaries between states change, and the scope of the activities of nation-states have also changed over time and are still changing. Do national boundaries matter?

The paper looks at two examples which help answer this question, each of which is concerned with economic sovereignty and which are intimately interconnected.

First, it seems likely that, even if there is open access to goods and services and capital flows, there will continue to be restrictions to the movement of people across many, but not all, boundaries. (Mobility within the EU is a major exception.) International mobility of labour is much less today than it was in the nineteenth century.

Second, while there will be policy convergence in some areas – most notably the loss of the power to restrict goods and services and capital flows – in many other areas policy seems likely to continue to reflect cultural and political differences and national objectives, albeit tempered by common technical and economic conditions. (For instance the United State and Canada can have different health care regimens, despite their border being the greatest trade border in the world.) Nor need there be a driving down of such policies to a lowest common denominator. The paper explores, not entirely satisfactorily, where the boundary between those policies which are likely to become internationalised and those over which a country may retain a degree of sovereignty, in part illustrated by the (aborted) Multilateral Agreement on Investment.

The paper’s concern is economic sovereignty, although parallels are briefly drawn with human rights sovereignty, and some attention is paid to the different US approaches to the use of the military (Iraq?) and trade (WTO disagreements).

For Fear Of Allah

The Koran prohibits interest, so how do Muslims borrow and lend
Listener: 11 September 2004.

Keywords: Macroeconomics & Money;

Launching his Christianity Without God, Lloyd Geering asked me when I would write a book about the economy without money. I said that anthropologist Raymond Firth had already done so (The Economics of the New Zealand Maori), but I would one day write a column about an economy without interest. Lloyd’s eyes twinkled. “Islam?” The Koran states, “Have fear of Allah and give up what remains of what is due to you of usury.”

The thousand-plus year older Jewish Torah has a more limited prohibition. Deuteronomy states, “To a stranger you may lend upon usury: but to your brother you may not lend on usury.” Because medieval Jews were prevented from entering most professions, they became expert moneylenders to Christians and were hated for it (recall Shylock). Ironically, their expertise was vital to the development of the modern economy, the reason that Cromwell permitted Jews to return to England from 1655.

The parable of the talents in the Christian gospels indicates that interest is permitted. (St Paul’s “the love of money is the root of all evil” is often misquoted by omitting the first three words.) The protestant theologian John Calvin interpreted “usury” as “unjustly exorbitant interest”. Today that meaning usually appears in an English dictionary. It allows reasonable interest payments as a recompense for forgoing the opportunity to spend immediately. (For “waiting”, as the great economist Alfred Marshall, son of the vicarage, described it.)

However, Muslims interpret the Koranic prohibition to mean all interest payments. One banker remarked, “There is no sin in the Koran … which could be as abhorrent and serious as dealing in riba [interest].”

An Islamic banker? The Koran does not prohibit private property, business, borrowing and lending, or banking. Its logic is that money may be advanced, providing the risk is shared between borrower and lender. Banks can exist: there are over 200 Islamic financial institutions in the world. But the return to the lender has to be a share in the profits and losses of the business. Easier said than done, and Islamic financial regimes and institutions have still to work out comprehensive details.

Individuals deposit their savings in an Islamic bank in a mudarabah account. It does not earn interest, but gets a share of the profits from the enterprises that the bank invests in. Borrowing is a little trickier. Instead of credit cards, there are debit cards. It is, however, difficult to borrow to build a new house. One Islamic banker explains that he is still completing his new house, because mortgages are not possible. He pays for developments out of his income. An existing house is easier. The bank purchases the house, adds a margin, and resells it to the putative owner, who pays the price off in equal monthly amounts, which sum to the price of the house.

“Aha,” you say, “the margin is effectively an interest rate.” Arithmetically, that is correct, but the bank takes all the risk if market interest rates change (and on-shares it with its depositors). More-over, Islamic bankers insist that there are moral principles as well. Any late fees have to be donated to charity. Donating a share of one’s income to charity, zakat, is a fundamental requirement of being a Muslim, more important – some say – than the pilgrimage to Mecca. And the bank is not to penalise a borrower who is genuinely broke.

In my reading of Islamic economics (it is not complete: I don’t know how they run monetary policy without interest rates), I am continually struck by the emphasis that it places on moral behaviour. One summary is that although conventional economics was “built to harness human nature, Islamic economics want to reform it”. And they are concerned with the spirit of the law, not its letter: “Playing semantics with God is very dangerous.”

Of course, Geering was not writing about a godless Christianity, but one with a different kind of god. Similarly interest-less Islamic borrowing and lending still have a return for the waiting. It is worth studying each to obtain a better understanding of one’s own system – and to respect the opinions of others.

Dealing with the Monetary Policy Trilemma

Notes for an informal economic discussion

Keywords: Macroeconomics & Money;

While pursuing my primary research interest of globalisation, a recently read paper reminded me of the ‘fundamental’ dilemma of monetary policy of an open economy, also called the ‘trilemma’ or the ‘irreconcilable trinity’.[1]

While nations may have three goals of
– currency convertibility (freedom of cross-border capital movements);
– a stable exchange rate; and
– an independent monetary policy oriented towards domestic objectives such as price stability;
the theory argues that an economy can attain only, at most, two out of three of them.

New Zealand monetary policy is predicated on the trilemma. In December 1984 we removed capital controls, and in March 1985 we floated the currency. Since then we have gone for the independent monetary policy and currency convertibility pair of objectives. As a result the exchange rate has had to fluctuate.

The strategy makes life difficult for the tradeable sector which exports and competes against imports, and whose success is at the heart of the growth process in a small open multisectoral economy like New Zealand. We compounded the difficulty by running an over-valued exchange rate, but even had we not, the profitability of the sector suffers from fluctuations in the rate. Buying exchange forward is some protection, but that costs money, lowering the exporter’s return. In any case, for every purchase of foreign exchange someone is selling it.

Is it possible to avoid the trilemma? If we did not care about one of the goals, there is no dilemma. An option might be to abandon full currency convertibility. A number of economists have condemned total convertibility for ‘hot money’ – short term capital movements – including James Tobin and Jagdish Bhagwati. Note they are not advocating restricting foreign domestic investment. Perhaps some time in the future, restraints on hot money will be internationally normal. Is there anything we can do in the interim?

Like many so-called ‘generalities’, the trilemma has underlying institutional assumptions, reflecting an American perspective that monetary policy bears all the weight of macro-policy, because the US constitution was constructed long before economic management was conceivable.

In other countries there are other policy instruments. A guided wage path is no longer possible here, given the weakness of the union movement, although unions still need to be responsible in their wage settlements. But fiscal policy can share the weight when pursuing domestic objectives. Insofar as it does, monetary policy can contribute to a stable and competitive exchange rate.

For as long as I can remember neither the Reserve Bank nor the Treasury have commented on the other’s macroeconomic responsibility. Even in the 1970s and 1980s, when fiscal management was disgraceful, the Bank made no public comment. As far as I know, there is no systematic thinking in either of the two institutions about how monetary and fiscal policy might be co-ordinated, although I welcome their macro-economic forecasting cooperation of recent years.

I appreciate why neither publicly comments on the other and how, given the Official Information Act, it is hard to have a rigorous internal discussions on macroeconomic co-ordination. Alas no New Zealand university is a centre of macroeconomic policy expertise, and a lack of research funding has undermined the NZIER’s traditional role as a macroeconomic thinktank.

The assumption that optimal monetary and fiscal policy can be separated is a nonsense, both empirically and theoretically. The trilemma exists in New Zealand as long as we fail to address how we might coordinate fiscal and monetary policy.

[1] M. Obstfeld and A.M. Taylor, “Globalization and Capital Markets” in M.D. Bordo, A.M. Taylor and J.G. Williamson Globalization in Historical Perspective (NBER/University of Chicago Press, 2003).

Reforming the Rma

The market will generate a good environmental outcome if all the property rights are allocated, providing transaction costs are zero.
Listener: 28 August, 2004.

Keywords: Environment & Resources;

As George Soros remarked, policy regimes are like marriage: whichever one you’re in, you wonder if another might be better. Thus it is with the Resource Management Act. We seem to have forgotten the shambolic arrangements that the Act swept away. But the RMA can be improved.

Its underlying economic theory – the Coase theorem – is intriguingly beautiful, but the limitations of its application are revealing. I shan’t prove the theorem, which of course only applies under certain assumptions. For this column’s purposes, it says that the market will generate a good environmental outcome if all the property rights – who can use, transform or transfer each resource – are allocated, providing transaction costs are zero. The notion of allocating property rights and letting the market take over is the spirit of the RMA, developed in the late 1980s during the high point of our fascination with the market, albeit with the purpose of sustainable management and regard for the life-supporting capacity of the environment.

But applying the principles of the theorem is like belling the cat. What are the relevant property rights and who gets them? It was a stroke of genius to give property rights to future generations via the Act’s sustainability provisions. But all the rest is murkier, and we have ended up with a tribunal system that is involved in identifying and allocating the rights and, at a remove, seeing the rights are enforced, a task that many environmentalists think is done very badly.

The catch is that a tribunal system introduces transaction costs, and we move outside the scope of the theorem. Many of the demands for reforms are to reduce those transaction costs. Business grumbles over the time and costs to make big decisions, although locals sometimes feel that they are cut out, especially as about 95 percent of resource consent applications are not publically notified.

The government has already given more resources to the Environmental Court so it hears appeals more quickly, and the backlog has been reduced from about 3000 cases to 1500 cases, including those in mediation. Local authorities have improved their performance. But the central government has failed to use the Act to provide national policy statements and standards on such things as energy and water.

Lurking behind this allocation of the property rights is the fact they can be fiddled to give valuable ones to some and not others. I won’t accuse the reform advocates of wanting to do this, but speeding up a decision can cut some people out – especially the fragmentally organised, who are typically the communities involved. On the other hand, the tribunal process generates pseudo-property rights when those without significant entitlements can cause sufficient delays in the process to have developers pay them to speed up decisions. The two issues are not unrelated, because cutting out illegitimate, but extortionate, claims may also cut out legitimate ones.

The central role of the transaction costs in the RMA process leads one to meditate on their importance in the economy generally, in contrast to the almost insignificant role they play in most economic analysis. This is all the more astonishing because economists – like lawyers and accountants – are part of the transaction costs on an economy. Yet, economic development, with its increasing complexity of the production process and the increasing sophistication of consumer demands, involves transaction activities growing faster than transformation activities.

Tim Hazledine of Auckland University calculates that 25.7 percent of all employed workers were in transaction activities in 1956, with the remainder in production activities. By 1998, the proportion had risen to 39.8 percent. Only an eighth of the transactors are in the public service: their numbers have been growing slightly more slowly than those in the private sector.

The economists’ task is to try to incorporate transaction costs more formally into economic theory, instead of pretending they don’t exist. In the interim, it seems a good idea to keep transaction costs as low as possible. Which is what should be done with the RMA process, without undermining the primary principles of the Act or the interests of the communities involved.

Paradigms Of New Zealand Economic Growth: a Memoir (part I)

This paper was written in august 2004, for no particular purpose other than to clarify my own ideas.
Part II

Keywords: Growth & Innovation; History of Ideas, Methodology & Philosophy;

Either this kind of aggregate economics appeals or it doesn’t. Personally I belong to both schools. Robert Solow (1957)

To 1974: The Aggregate Supply-side Paradigm
The Crucial Experiment of 1974
1975 to 1981
1981 to 1986
The Grand Policy Break and Economic Modelling
The Intervention and Allocation Debate
Leaving the Institute
1986 to 1997
International Comparisons
Bryan Philpott
The Economy After 1985
Looking for the Recovery

Paradigms of New Zealand Economic Growth: A Memoir II
The Double Step Chart
After 1997
Back to Econometric Estimation
Characterising Economic Growth
Standard Growth
Turbo-growth
The Effect of Shocks
Paradigm Conflict

It is now thirty years since when in 1974 I stumbled on the ‘crucial experiment’ which has led to a story of New Zealand’s economic growth, which the conventional wisdom still has yet to engage properly, as it clings to the ‘aggregate supply-side paradigm’ (ASSP).

To 1974: The Aggregate Supply-side Paradigm

I was almost at the beginning of the modern study of growth economics in New Zealand. It was not practical before the 1950s, because data bases were inadequate. Indeed some critical ones were not available until the 1980s, and in some ways they are still not adequate. The other crucial requirement was the theoretical paradigm, which might be said to have been first set out in 1957 in Robert Solow’s seminal paper ‘Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function’.

The paper has two key elements. First it enables some quantification of the growth process, and second it shows that economic growth is not simply a matter of additional labour and capital. There is something else which drives increasing output per worker which Solow called ‘technical progress’. The quantification says that this ‘something else’ is perhaps four times more important than extra capital per worker.

Over the following fifty years, it has proved very difficult to explain the ‘something else’ with any precision. In 1962 Tommy Balogh and Paul Streeten called it a ‘coefficient of ignorance’, the unexplained residual, and that is the way it largely remains forty and more years on, with surprisingly little evidence of the causal links which generate its magnitude. Even so it is hard to avoid using the notion, as Part V of my In Stormy Seas does.

However, underpinning Solow’s theory is a notion which has dominated much thinking about growth ever since. It is there in the paper’s title: ‘the aggregate production function’. This means that one does not think of total output of an economy simply as the sum of all the (net) outputs of the various businesses in the economy. Rather, one treats the total output as if it were a single good produced by a single business using two separate inputs of labour and capital (plus the mysterious ‘technical progress’).

This aggregation to one commodity and two inputs is an enormous simplification for if it is true – or near enough to true – it means that an economist does not have to worry about individual businesses or sectors, in order to explain economic growth. It is such a seductive idea that it has been one of the workhorses of economics ever since, and it underpins the New Zealand conventional wisdom (and that of many other economists). Hence the paradigm’s entitlement to a name – the ‘aggregate supply-side paradigm’ – and an acronym – ‘ASSP’.

The ‘supply-side’ implies there is little attention to demand effects. Prices are almost irrelevant to the paradigm. In the old fashioned discourse one would call ‘Stalinists’ those who only use ASSP for research purposes, that is they are concerned only with the real side of the economy, like a Stalinist planner, ignoring the role of prices in economic development.

At first I was a committed ASSP adherent too. Indeed I was fortunate, because the director, Conrad Blyth of the NZIER where I worked from late 1963 to 1966, had completed a PhD in capital theory in the late 1950s, and cottoned onto the ASSP paradigm very quickly (as some of the research papers he published then demonstrate).

As Solow’s quotation which begins this paper indicates, virtually all users of ASSP have a split personality, because they apply much more disaggregated accounts of the economy when it suits them. It is not uncommon even today to listen to a paper whose research is based upon ASSP, and then hear the presenter jumps to policy conclusions which have nothing to do with it but come from a different – more disaggregated – paradigm.

(Sometimes it is as if economists have two tool kits, or their brain has been separated into two uncoordinated parts. I was intrigued recently by Stephen Pinker’s description of humans whose corpus callosums had been severed so their brains were literally two separate hemispheres. If one ‘brain’ was given an instruction unbeknownst to the other, the second ‘brain’ would make up an explanation of what happened which was plausible but wrong. ‘For instance, if an experimenter flashed the command “WALK” to the right hemisphere (by keeping it in the part of the visual field that only the right hemisphere can see), the person will … walk out of the room. But when the … person’s left hemisphere is asked why he just got up he will say in all sincerity, “To get a coke” rather than “I dont really know”.’ (The Blank Slate, p.43). Sometimes that seems to happen as economists switch between two paradigms.)

The two (and more) paradigm user certainly applies to me. I think of each as a part of one’s tool-kit, each paradigm being a tool to be used for a particular purpose. The skilled craftsman not only loves each instrument-paradigm, but knows its strengths and weaknesses. Choosing the right tool is a part of the skill.

For our purposes, the central point is that, even though it may derive its policy conclusions from other paradigms, the conventional wisdom uses the ASSP to analyse New Zealand’s economic growth. I no longer do. Why I changed my mind probably began in 1974, with what in the methodology of science may be called the ‘critical experiment’.

(The Solow paradigm was extended about 20 years ago by ‘endogenous growth theory’. This has not really been taken up by the New Zealand conventional wisdom yet, so I will not refer further to it. It is interesting, but like the Solow based paradigm so aggregate it does not provide many insights. I add that I like the notion of technology embodied in labour and capital: you cant have technology without the other two, but this is a much older idea.)

The ‘Crucial Experiment’ of 1974

Returning to New Zealand in late 1970, I had decided to focus my research activity on the income distribution, which eventually culminated in Income Distribution in New Zealand. The reasons for the choice need not concern us here, although one was I wanted to look at the New Zealand economy (and political economy) through a different prism from that which was usual.

By 1974 I had constructed two series of the return on wealth, each of which in principle reflected the same underlying notion, although given the independent data bases from which they constructed I did not expect the series to correspond exactly. But to my dismay, I found that one increased through time and the other decreased. After all, one of the traditional questions of economics was whether there is a falling rate of profit or not. Between them, the series answered ‘yes’ and ‘no’. Botheration.

I recall that one night – it must have been Saturday – musing over this, it occurred to me that the two series did not cover exactly the same period. The different trends could be explained by the underlying series rising peaking and then falling. That required a statistical calculation. In those days there were not personal computers, and certainly one did not keep the old mechanical calculators at home. So somewhat agitated – to use a nineteenth century expression – I biked out to the Ilam campus the following day – Sunday – and ran a quadratic (a curved trend) through both sets of data. Glory be, there was the curvature with the peak in the mid-to-late 1960s.

Often solving one research problem creates another. The crucial experiment resolved the inconsistency but why had the peak occurred? I was out of New Zealand from late 1966 to late 1970, so I did not have direct experience of the period. So I had to read about what happened, and analyse the data.

Eventually I tracked down the critical change. There are a number of candidates – including the devaluation of 1967, and the Nil Wage Order of 1968, although those two ought to have boosted the return on wealth, not depressed it. The evidence settled on the spectacular collapse in the wool price in December 1966, which was the earliest candidate; it generally coincided with the peaks I had estimates, and it explained the other candidates. In those days wool made up about forty percent of all exports by value, and with sheep meats, the contribution of sheep farmers and processors came to about 65 percent of all export receipts. So a wool price fall of about 40 percent – permanent, except for a spike in 1972 and 1973 – was a nasty shock to the export economy.

The wool price appears in the terms of trade, the price of exports divided by the price of imports. That they tended to fall – sometimes dramatically – had long been a concern of New Zealand economists given the way they had plunged in the early 1930s. (The official series only started in 1926. Later I was to construct a series which went back to the 1850s.) Although born a decade after the Great Depression, I was aware of this concern, particularly through Bill Sutch and also in the international development literature. It argued there was an inevitable tendency for the price of primary commodities (such as wool, meat and dairy products) to fall relative to the price of manufactures, and so the terms of trade of primary producing countries (such as New Zealand) would decline in the long time, making economic growth more difficult for third world countries (and New Zealand).

I have done much research and reading on this over the years, and I do not now think – I may have in the past – that it is inevitable that the terms of trade for primary producers will decline. The evidence is that different primary products have different price patterns. Resource constrained ones – oil and fish – may result in a tendency for their relative price to rise, perhaps too for minerals and timber. The price experience of meat and dairy products – and no doubt other ones I have not investigated (cotton? sugar?) – in part reflects dumping on to world markets by rich countries who subsidise their farm producers to over -production . This is not an inevitable policy response, as the Doha Round shows. Some products – such as wool, red meat, and butter – have been squeezed by substitutes, by health fashions and saturated consumption in key (affluent) markets. But while there is no inevitability of decline, the prudent country would want a degree of diversification by export commodity and country.

I began collecting data series which showed a change in trend following 1966. As well as the terms of trade and the return on wealth, they included the profitably of farming, agricultural output, growth of output, unemployment and inflation. (When I wrote a Listener column about this in May 1979, a reader suggested I look at installed telephones, and. sure enough, there was a break about then too.) It is not hard to write a story about how these are inter-related, as an the external shock of a significant fall in the terms of trade impacted on some important sectors of the economy, which fed through to the rest of the economy, including slowing the growth of the economy.

As I recall, I had largely got this broad framework together by the mid 1970s, well before the long term consequences of the entry of Britain into the (now) European Union in 1973 or the oil price hike of 1974 would be evident in the data. Moreover the structural break was before 1973. Many people focus on the 1973 break with Britain: undoubtedly an emotional break for them, especially if they have a colonial mentality. The oil price shock (which also depressed the terms of trade) is a better candidate for a later date. I have never completely ruled it out, for it is difficult to separate the oil price effect from the short-term world commodity boom which preceded it. My work has tended to suggest that the oil price hike took New Zealand export prices back to where they were tracking before the boom. (While the price of imports lifted, so did the price of some exports – meat and dairy products – sold to the now more affluent oil producers.) Some very recent work – reported below – suggests that there may have been an additional effect from the oil price hike – or even possibly the British entry to the EU. Even so the 1966 effect appears larger and is, of course, earlier.

About this time, probably in 1975, I hit a major methodological crisis: the ‘capital reversing debate’. We dont need to go through it here, except to say it raises serious questions about the practical possibility of aggregating to a single production function in a meaningful way. It may not affect the ASSP because it is related to anomalous behaviour in prices (factor returns), and the ASSP is not very dependent upon these prices. Working between macro-economic aggregate and sectoral disaggregation the phenomenon was much more distressing, and I even contemplated giving up economics. Today I try to work at as a disaggregated level as I can, and always check when working at high levels of aggregation that capital reversing would not upset the story.

While the capital reversing debate was painful, it enabled me to have an understanding of what practically ‘technology’ might mean and how it might be fitted into an account of growth, without the handwaving of a technical progress index. Joan Robinson suggested we think of technology as blueprints, descriptions of how one might combine resources commodities and capital into output. I describe some of the insights of this micro-approach below.

1975 to 1981

As my publications list shows, I proceeded on a wide front after this discovery, continuing to work on distributional economics, but also getting sucked into the growth and macroeconomic implications of the findings, including investigating earlier periods of New Zealand economic history to see if the evolving theory worked.

The work for this period culminates in my inaugural address as director of the NZIER in 1982: External Impact and Internal Response: The New Zealand Economy in the 1970s and 1980s. It follows the 1979 Listener column, albeit in more detail, describing how the terms of trade fall from 1966 impacted on the profitability of the farm sector, then onto farm output, and the economy as a whole, again emphasising that numerous data series show a structural break in the 1966 to 1968 period.

The paper also sets out a formal model, from orthodox international trade theory, of the impact of the terms of trade on the production possibilities and hence output and growth. I recall one of the brighter young economists of the day saying after the lecture he thought I had got it wrong, and he would come back to me. He never did, and to this day – as a respected economist – he continues to use the ASSP without any awareness of the consequence of sector and price shifts. The ASSP assumes that economic output can be characterised by a single commodity. It makes no sense to export and import this same commodity. So the ASSP, ignoring the external sector all together and focussing on domestic production, is not very useful for economies where international trade is important. Now just suppose that the poor growth performance had something to do with the external sector. Those who relied solely upon the ASSP would have no way of investigating what happened.

Reflecting all these years later, I realise that I was doing something unorthodox in terms of the economics of the day. The tool kit – the various bit of economic theory I applied – was unquestionably orthodox, but I used it imaginatively, combining different tools for particular purposes. My approach has been eclectic. Faced by a problem, I draw from the tool kit any tools that seem useful. Having been alerted to a structural problem in the post-1966 era, I did not go back to a particular paradigm, but looked around for the tools which seemed relevant, synthesising them to what proves to be a different paradigm, which is treated as unorthodox by the conventional wisdom, even though every element of it is orthodox. Of course, that is the way intellectual progress occurs, with the conventional wisdom typically lagging behind.

In particular, once I had identified that the rupture was due to a price shock (a change in relative prices) I had to go outside the ASSP, which has no prices, and look for other parts of economic theory which did. Naturally I fell upon the theory of international trade and general equilibrium analysis, which both contain numerous commodities and hence have relative prices between them. So sectors became important, since different prices impacted differently on different sectors, as I illustrated earlier with the farm sector.

I called the paradigm the ‘Small Open Multisectoral Economy’ or SOME. Small because New Zealand is a small player in the world economy and so is largely a price-taker for exports, imports and foreign capital. Open because international engagement is central to the New Zealand economy. Multisectoral because other than in the short run, relative changes in sectors (and the prices which influence these changes) are crucial in the understanding of the economy’s behaviour. The three concepts are closely related, in that the most important production sectors – the absolute minimum one can get away with – are the exportable sector (which provides exports and some domestic expenditure), the importable sector (which competes with imports) and non-tradeables which are not directly influenced by international trade.

Note that three sectors means three prices and two price relatives. Initially I only looked at the terms of trade – the ratio of the price of exportables to importables – but by the early 1980s I was also concerned about the second price relative which is the real exchange rate – the ratio of non-tradeables over tradeables (although there are other ways of measuring it). I’ll be coming back to that later, but in passing I observe that some New Zealand economist confuse the real exchange rate and the terms of trade, perhaps because they have difficulty getting from a one commodity model to a multi-commodity one. There is an instance in a New Zealand textbook, and only this year a recent graduate came up to me and insisted that his teachers had not made the distinction. (Sigh)

Once having crossed the threshold from a single commodity to a two or three sector one, there is potentially no stopping, so the exact number of sectors depends upon the precise question that is being answered. In In Stormy Seas I said that I frequently think of a six sector model: agriculture; other exportables; hydrocarbons; other importables; market non-tradeables; government services. But of course I will go down to a greater level of disaggregation if necessary. I have long thought – certainly since 1982 – that one of the greatest achievements of the New Zealand economy in the 1970s was the diversification of exports by commodity and country, although I did not know then that it was the greatest in the OECD according to some work done by John Gould. But how can the ASSP acknowledge that, given there are no exports, let alone different kinds of exports, in the paradigm?

1981-1986

The next five years were spent as director of the NZIER. I had come on the basis that it was a research institution, but increasingly its work was dominated by having to raise money from consultancy. Now consultancy can enhance research by providing a wider perspective and unusual experiences. Sometimes it makes a surplus which can be invested in research. But it became more difficult over the years, especially as I was also trying to run a sophisticated macro-economic forecasting unit, rather than the mechanically auto-regressive ones that became common in later years, and that required funding for research too.

A summary of the research program over the five years will be found in my 1986 valedictory address The Exchange Rate Since 1981: Performance and Policy. By now terms of trade shocks were not important, and the focus was on the real exchange rate, which had risen sharply in 1985 following the floating of the exchange rate. The path of the economy was exactly what SOME would predict. A higher exchange rate, like a lower terms of trade, reduces the profitability of the tradeable sector (i.e exportables and importables), their expansion slows down, and so does economic growth. Once again the ASSR could make no prediction, lacking exports and prices.

The Grand Policy Break and Economic Modelling

This led to the grand policy break I had with the conventional wisdom. It was apparent from Economic Management, the Treasury 1984 post-election briefing – not to mention the odd conversation with and other published paper by officials – that there were some gaps in the Treasury thinking, as well as some very casual use of statistical data. Through much of the next two years, I assumed that they knew what they were doing, and scoured official papers to identify the rigorous underpinning model which they were using. In the end I decided that there was not one.

I was trained – extremely well by Derek Lawden at the University of Canterbury – as an applied mathematician, which involves describing the world by models characterised by a set of equations. Analytical economics does this too, so it is a matter of habit that when someone is talking about the economy I try to work out her or his formal consistent economic model. In a surprising number of occasions one becomes aware they have none. The kindest thing is to suggest their implicit model is incomplete, although some seem to have no more than a few relationships held together by an ideology.

It is difficult to explain this briefly to someone untrained in modelling, so I am going to give a very simple example from recent times. Suppose one says that the reason for New Zealand’s poor economic performance is its distance from significant markets. I will challenge that proposition with evidence which contradicts the assertion (in one of its forms) later, but there are those who say it despite the evidence, reflecting a bad habit in New Zealand public discussion to think that any two facts are necessarily connected if there is a vague feeling they ought to be.

Now it is possible to write a equation connecting distance and income in two fundamentally different ways. I wont here, but one says that the level of income is depressed, because New Zealand has to pay a lot to ship its products overseas (and so on) so we dont get as good a return for our exports (after these costs) as we would if we were closer. There is no problem formulating the relationship this way. The second implicit equation is that the (proportional) growth of income is depressed by distance from markets. Now that is a really interesting proposition (even if it is complicated by effective distance getting shorter). But what mechanism have the advocates got in mind? I listened to them really carefully, and soon recognised that they explain the second equation about growth by referring to the first equation about levels. It is a confusion, like saying to a traffic officer that you had not exceed the 50kph speed limit because you only drove 40kms.

Many people – including economists – get confused between growth and accelerating growth, between levels and changes in levels. Perhaps the following (imperfect) metaphor might help. Suppose we treat the level of per capita GDP as the distance a car has gone. The rate of growth of GDP is the speed of the car. Very often the two are confused as in the last sentences of the previous paragraph. Because people dont model well, the confusion is endemic.

As it became clear that the advocates of the reforms did not have a complete account of the economic model they were using, I looked for the ‘missing equation(s)’. I dont want to get too technical here but, as every modeller knows, an economy with an external sector (i.e. exports and imports) requires one additional equation to ‘close’ the model, that is to enable all the equations to be solved. There are a number of possible candidates including full employment, a zero deficit in the balance of payments, no inflation, a particular level of economic growth, and so on. Experience shows that the choice of that final equation leads to quite different outcomes. So which one did the advocates of the policies of the late 1980s think applied? The answer proved to be, as far as I could make out, they were not even aware that there was a problem. At a certain point they just put their hands together and prayed that the economy would ‘close’ itself.

In practice the closure came via the Reserve Bank’s monetary policy, although those administering it seemed unaware what they were doing. Their missing equation was the determination of the exchange rate. The conventional wisdom seemed to think that the market would set its own level, but it was unclear how. In principle the economy could settle around any given nominal exchange rate, although that had implications for output, employment, inflation and growth. Their analysis overlooked the fact that the fiscal and monetary actions of the government would impact on the exchange rate, or perhaps it assumed – wrongly – that the impacts were small and could be ignored. So they ran a fiscal position which would drive up the exchange rate, while the RBNZ ‘closure’ involved a high exchange rate too, with the outcome of slower growth and unemployment (albeit with disinflation). Which is exactly what happened.

Now you may think this has little to do with the paradigmatic clash. But the RBNZ model of money in the economy was closely related to the ASSP, because it assumed that there is a single commodity. If it did not, the RBNZ would have to think about multiple prices in an economy, and different rates of inflation, and that would undermine much of the rhetoric that surrounds monetary policy. (Nowadays the RBNZ looks at a number of price indexes, even if the policy targets agreement is about only one of them, the Consumer Price Index.)

The Intervention and Allocation Debate

Another part of the conventional wisdom’s brain talked about the allocative gains from microeconomic reform. Now much of my life as an economist has been about the tension between the success of the market mechanism and the failure of the market mechanism. The world is dominated by extremists who mention only one of theses features, and ignore the complexity. But the good Lord never gave me such simple beliefs, and in any case the balance has to be found in the particularities of the empirical evidence.

So when in the late 1970s, there arose the argument that New Zealand’s poor growth rate was a consequence of the high degree of interference with the market, I began to look around for empirical evidence. By this time there was a well established paradigm which calculated the losses due to misallocation of resources from market intervention, especially border protection. So I trawled through the research (much of which was done by Bryan Philpott, see below). None of the research showed a gain from the total elimination of border protection of more than 1 percent of GDP. (Actually one did, but it proved to be that a decimal point had been misplaced so a .7 percent increase became a 7 percent increase.) Given such a minuscule change – I was looking to explain a 20 plus percent loss over the first 20 years of the post-war era – I concluded that even were we to add in allocative gains from internal interventions, inappropriate intervention would explain only a very small proportion of the decline.

The smallness of the gains from eliminating protection is not surprising. Were there big gains in inefficiency from an intervention, a shrewd economic manager could work out how to reap them, while compensating losers. If the gains are small it is much less possible to do this. Disputes over protection are heated, not because the gains to the nation of eliminating it are large, but because they are small. However protection changes the incomes between various groups in the economy very substantially, so that if it is removed some people make large gains and some people make almost as large losses. But a dispute about distribution is too naked, so as with taxes, it has to be dressed up as a dispute about allocative gains and efficiency, just as the tax debate is presented today.

Because those who argued against border protection were bereft of evidence, they changed the rules, and focussed on effective rates of protection. If they are big they are bad in efficiency terms but you dont have to know a lot of economics to realise a big effective rate of protection (I am avoiding telling you how to measure them) means a big loss of efficiency. However the anti-protectionists made the equation even if they had no analytic reason for doing so.

Things became even more peculiar when they were calculated by different ways for manufacturing from agriculture, but then presented as if they were the same. You dont have to be a rocket scientist to know if one length is measure with a foot rule and the other with a theodolite, one takes care in any comparison. But so passionate was the debate that an obvious point was ignored.

Its get worse. The calculation – I am avoiding the technical details – requires that the cost excess in each industry be estimated. The cost excesses were calculated in the case of manufacturing but they were assumed (yes, ‘assumed’) in the case of farming. Initially they were assumed to be 10 or 20 or 30 percent, that is farmers had to pay an extra 10 or 20 or 30 percent, for all their inputs because of border protection, which would be quite a penalty. Eventually the debate forgot these figures were assumptions and settled on the mid rate as the true rate. So everyone wandered around talking about the 20 percent cost excess farmers faced. Farmers were most surprised that when we stripped out border protection they did not have a spectacular fall in their farm costs, and spent the 1990s hunting around for the gains they had been promised but which did not occur.

They should not have been surprised. In 1986 Bryan Philpott provided estimates of the cost excesses for farming and found they were 3 percent for current inputs and 5 percent for capital inputs, tiny by comparison with the assumed rates. The 20 percent gains never turned up, simply because they were not there. (Some farmers were sold down the line by their own organisations as a result, because they gave up significant support in exchange for almost non-existent concessions.)

When the interventions began being stripped away from 1984 I knew the research evidence did not support the extravagant promises by the ideologues. Of course, I could have been wrong, but I am not at all surprised that the research projections out-performed the extremist promises. There were no great gains from abandoning allocation, either on the level of output or its growth rate.

There is an irony in all this. If the theory of misallocation from intervention were correct, the ASSP would work even more clumsily. Again we have the case of one side of the brain saying one thing and the other saying the other.

Perhaps they were arguing that the costs of intervention, while mysterious, were still significant, and that removal of intervention would accelerate economic growth. However our economic history contradicted this, although I was not able to quantify it exactly until 1990. In the 1980s I could point out that in the early 1950s New Zealand had one of highest per capita GDPs in the world. Yet in the previous decades prior to 1950, intervention had increased the New Zealand economy. So where the correlation? In 1990 I provided an estimate of New Zealand’s volume GDP which showed that 1935 to 1945 was the period when New Zealand had its faster growth rate ever. And it was the period that interventions were imposed thickest and fastest.

Now lest I be misunderstood – not by you dear reader but you would be surprised at the speed at which some members of my profession turn correlation into causation while assuming that if one disagrees with their analysis one must support totally opposite policies – I dont believe that returning to the intervention levels of the 1940s would accelerate economic growth, and certainly the post 1935 experience does not prove that. On the whole I support low levels of intervention because the market gives consumers more choice and producers more flexibility, and because a government has so many important things to do it should not muck around with interventions which at best are of marginal benefit. However as my extensive writings show, there are places where I support intervening, and not only to get a fairer society.

Leaving the Institute

It was not an easy decision to leave the NZIER when my five year term ended, despite being offered a renewal. In a way it has permanently broken my heart. But I concluded that the NZIER was being steadily pushed away from research into consulting, which has happened despite, a marvellous rear guard action by Alan Bollard who took over as director at the end of the year, maintaining a really interesting industrial research program (although, alas, the macroeconomic one fell away). And in any case, I was by now in deep conflict with the conventional wisdom of the Treasury and the Reserve Bank: while nominally the NZIER is ‘independent’, the Wellington environment is more complicated than that.

I am proud of my valedictory speech, not only because it reflects the quality research program I had managed to run over the five years (on the smell of an oily rag), but also because with hindsight I got it broadly correct. In particular it was gloomy about the prospects of the New Zealand economy given the high exchange rate strategy, concluding ‘some paths are self destructive. I fear we could be on one at the moment, for the long term consequences of an over-valued exchange rate is both an increase in total overseas debt, with a reduction in investment in the tradeable sector, and hence in the nation’s ability to service the debt.’

Saying the exchange rate presents a problem to economic performance is no surprise today, but it was then for the conventional wisdom assumed that the market rate was the appropriate one for economic growth. Alas, the rate set by fiscal and monetary policy would generate stagnation. And even nowadays, the lesson is ignored in ASSP circles. I recently spent a couple of days at an officially sponsored seminar on productivity where the ASSP so dominant that I dont think the exchange rate was mentioned at all.

1986 to 1997

All this was before the six year stagnation from 1987. I went out as a consultant, doing lots of interesting work. However, rather than take the high returns of consultancy by working long hours (which could have compromised my independence), or taking time off, I chose a modest income by consultancy standards and used the spare time for further research and writing, culminating in the publication of In Stormy Seas: The Post-war New Zealand Economy| in 1997. (For various reasons it was a couple of years later than planned. I should also add that on occasions I got a little research funding to support the work, although funding for research was not nearly as generous then as it is today.) There are three salient events to report over this period.

International Comparisons

The first began in early 1987 when I was at the university of Melbourne as a visiting professor (the Downing Fellow), and became aware of the intense Australian interest in growth economics. Earlier in the decade the University of Pennsylvania had produced estimates of countries’ GDP (i.e. output) in the same prices, which made comparisons between the size of the economies more valid. GDP per capita at purchasing power parity (PPP) prices are somewhat more reliable than the previous estimates based on exchange rates – I was scathing about those in my 1986 lecture. I extended my work to use this database. Over a decade later they are now used in the New Zealand ASSP, and in the rhetoric of public debate.

Unfortunately the ASSP and the rhetoric uses the data uncritically, paying little attention to their accuracy. I spent a lot of time working on the accuracy of New Zealand’s GDP data (see Appendix 2 of In Stormy Seas and the related working papers) and am confident that on occasions the reported data has been misleading. I could not check the international comparisons with the same intensity, although the OECD 1987 figures gives an indication of the problems.

For instance, its international cost of housing was based on the cost of building a representative two-up-two-down brick terraced house. When asked for the cost, the New Zealand statisticians went to builders who gulped, having never built one, and gave a price based on what they would tender, without allowing for the savings they would make after having the experience of building hundreds. The cost was inappropriately high, with the result that the estimates 1987 have New Zealand investment too low. This was remedied in the 1990 round although getting international quality comparisons of investment goods still remains problematic, while when it comes to comparing the government sectors, the practice is to assume all civil servants with the same qualifications are equally productive. Oops there I go again, thinking about sectors. Tut-tut.

Even after intense effort to improve data quality, the changes between estimates at each point in time 1990, 1993, 1996, 1999, and soon 2002, do not connect with the GDP changes between them estimated by the official statisticians. Sometimes the differences are huge, certainly more than can be explained by errors in the measurement of GDP. Nobody is sure why. The sensible thing is to use the data cautiously.

It may seem odd that the local ASSP is so immune to the problems of data quality. It reflects, I think, that it does not push research frontiers, but works well within them. In one sense the data does not matter, as the other half of the brain gets on with policies which are only tenuously connected with the ASSP.

Very recently – I am writing this in 2004 and to my knowledge the issue only became apparent in late 2003 – there has been a realisation that the measured described as ‘GDP per capita at purchasing power parity’ does not measure production at all. It measures income. They are exactly equal at market prices, but they need not be equal at any other prices – and generally are not at PPP ones. One source of difference for New Zealand is that the practice of some rich countries of dumping products which compete with New Zealand exports not only lowers New Zealand’s foreign receipts, but lowers its income relative to its production at PPP prices. We dont know how big that is, but one study found a gap of around 9 percent in the estimate for Portugal relative to the US. New Zealand’s gap is likely to be more since it more greatly suffers from dumping.

Thus the international GDP comparisons do not compare productive power but expenditure power. The latter is useful for assessing material standard of living – if that be important – but it is of much less use for international productivity comparisons, and hence for the ASSP – if it really matters.

My approach has been to use the international GDP comparisons for illustration, but not to rely on them too much for research (or, for that matter, policy) conclusions. The conventional wisdom has gone the opposite direction, placing greater weight on the data than it can possibly bear. Perhaps it is a matter of rhetoric rather than analysis, a conclusion forced upon one by the oddity of the way the ASSP research has progressed.

Their emphasis has been on ‘rankings’ – that is the number of OECD countries which are above New Zealand on the (flawed) measure of GDP per capita – rather than ‘relativity’ – how New Zealand’s level compares with the average.

Any competent quantitative social science would be alerted to the peculiarity of this choice. Rankings involve ‘ordinal’ measures, while relativities involve ‘cardinals’. A child can work with ordinals, that is count, but their limitations soon become apparent and the child moves on to adding, that is using numbers as cardinals. Ordinals are a much more primitive means of handling numbers, and yet involve much clumsiness. For that reason their statistical properties are less understood. (Technically, any statistician can instantly tell you about the properties of the mean of a sample, a cardinal measure, but would fumble over the same characteristics of the equivalent ordinal measure – the median.)

I rejected the use of rankings when I first looked at the international data, a matter so obvious to me that I argued the case only briefly in In Stormy Seas . Yet a decade later they were fashionable, although I detect some progress in the last year. Perhaps the analysis is entering the quantitative primers.

There is one further complication, explained below. But to foreshadow it: the aggregates, even if accurate, do not mean a lot. One needs to know about what is happening by sector.

Bryan Philpott

Returning from the University of Melbourne, I settled into a routine of doing enough contract work to make a living, using the spare time to do public interest research. I began to see Bryan Philpott who had just retired from the McCarthy Chair of Economics at the nearby Victoria University of Wellington, weekly when we were both there, and we had grand old chats, sharing analysis, discussing recent developments, exchanging research findings, reviewing policies. It was the very collegial relationship which should go on within any university economics department. But that belongs to another memoir.

The University’s treatment of Bryan, the most distinguished holder of the chair, after retirement was a puzzle. They gave him an office plus storage, and access to facilities like library and computing, and left him alone to continue his research program. There was, apparently, no recognition of the inherent value of the research program, nor of the enormous data base which Bryan had built up. They could have appointed staff who would work with him, or help preserve the data base which he continued to extend. It was almost as if they did not care about research and it was no surprise that when the performance based research assessments were reported in 2004, the university’s economics department was not among the top ones.

Bryan had been an earlier user of the ASSP, but by the late 1960s he had moved on working with ‘Computational General Equilibrium’ (CGE) Models which were empirically based sectoral representations of the economy, and therefore had inter-sectoral prices. For this memoir’s purposes this is all we need to know about them.

What probably drove Bryan away from a crude ASSP position, in addition to his general intelligence and enthusiasm, was trying to model the economy for the 1968 National Development Conference, following the 1967 devaluation precipitated by the 1966 wool price collapse. I was not there, but I read the reports in the 1970s, and was struck by how those involved, Bryan included, were struggling to get their head around what happens when a number of major prices in the economy change dramatically. The answers are obvious enough now to me – and no doubt now to them – but the resolution of the challenge required moving away from a single commodity view of the world to a more disaggregated one.

Not only did the university fail to support the research program – which, alas, died with Bryan in 2000 – but neither did officialdom. One might say that they no longer needed the research and transferred the funding to other priorities, although they left an impression that they abandoned Bryan because his research contradicted their policy premises. ( In fact the predictions based on his conclusions were rather closer to actual outcome that the optimistic forecasts of the conventional wisdom.)

Moreover, at a later stage overseas consultants were hired to carry out the sort of modelling that Bryan and his students were expert at. You will have to ask the hirers why they did so, but while the contractors were competent, their lack of knowledge of the New Zealand economy often left much to be desired.

I recall Bryan coming back from a university seminar on some Business Roundtable commissioned research – I was not invited – remarking that the researchers had found that the burden of taxation had risen following the reforms of the 1980s. Now one does not have to be a Business Roundtable extremist to know that just has to be a nonsense, because one of the successes of the period was the substantial improvement in the efficiency of the tax system. (What happened to equity is more contentious.) This judgement is based on orthodox economics, and of course the foreign researchers were unquestionably orthodox. Bryan went on that the research assumed leisure as a response to tax rates, so it treated the rise in unemployment in the late 1980s as overtaxed workers choosing leisure (rather than due to economic stagnation arising from the over-valued exchange rate). When I looked at the paper, he proved to be quite right, a timely reminder that this man in his late 70s was still perceptive relative to overseas contractors, who knew little about the New Zealand economy.

One of the features of New Zealand is that once inside, people get a second chance following a cockup. So the overseas contractors were contracted by the Treasury to measure Solow’s index of aggregate technical progress, again an expertise of Bryan (who also did it by sector by sector, a much more revealing exercise). Again it was Bryan who first drew my attention to their use of an invalid capital series, a result of their not understanding the New Zealand data. It raised serious doubts of the validity of the conclusion, since ultimately the calculation is based on just three series – output, labour and capital – so if any is of poor quality the result is likely to be undermined. (Later work by me showed the output series was flawed and by Simon Chapple that the labour series was also flawed. Even so, the work is still quoted.)

I have read most of the research reports by Bryan and his students – and learned much. I have already mentioned the closure problem and the sensitivity of the outcome to the way it was resolved. The other obvious lesson was the practical importance of sectoral analysis. Some CGE modelling runs resulted in behaviour close enough to an ASSP single commodity outcome, but in other runs the outcomes were very different from a prediction of what was happening based on a single commodity economy.

Suppose New Zealand’s production per worker (properly measured) is less than the OECD average. So what? GDP is an aggregate of numerous businesses which are grouped into sectors. At the very least we want to know which sectors – as a proxy for the akin businesses – are below the OECD average, and which are above. Looking at only the aggregate implicitly assumes all business must have equally poor productivity. That surely cannot be true. We know it is not true in the case of the government sector, because it is measured so that all OECD government sectors are equally productive after adjusting for the measured quality of the workforce (a faute de mieux I hasten to add). And we would be astonished if the New Zealand farming sector had a lower productivity than the OECD average. So which sectors are letting us down and why?

International sectoral comparisons are a relatively new area of research, so one can but conjecture answers to this question, as we ponder each sector. It may not be manufacturing – the usual suspect – once we adjust for its composition, for subsector by subsector New Zealand manufacturing may be relatively productive. In any case, would lower productivity manufacturing be sufficient to explain the entire 15 percent or so reduction? (The answer is no, for given its size it would have to have zero productivity if all other sectors were average.)

I shant go through the other sectors, even though I once tried to do international comparisons. At the end of the day, we just dont know. My guess is there are some sectors which are relatively weak, in some cases because of distribution costs in a low density country with a rugged terrain and a strait in the middle, that for various reasons our industry composition may be unfavourable, and that the international income estimate substantially underestimates true New Zealand output (relative to the OECD average). Suppose I am right. What does one make of the policy proposals – such as cutting corporation tax – which pop out of the ASSP, albeit with no logical connection? Should not my musings be at least explored?

This of course, does not explain the relatively low GDP growth rate over the period. That is addressed in the next subsection.

The Economy After 1985

When I left the NZIER in mid 1986, the economy was also struggling. It had a brief expansion fuelled by a fiscal stimulus, monetary slackness, and a wild unsustainable financial boom, consequential on the abandonment of the old regulatory framework and the failure to impose another one. Ian Cross once told me that he had reviewed the financial pages in early 1987 and that only two writers said that the sharemarket prices were then too high. The other was Muldoon – the strange company one keeps. Any claim to fame I have here was due to my interpreting some others’ research which suggested the P/E ratios of shares – the price of shares relative to the earnings they were generating – were wildly above their long term average. I confess to I naively assuming that the reported earnings per share was honest. In fact they were seriously overestimated, so my forebodings of overpriced shares were on the conservative side.

Underpinning my scepticism of the P/E ratios was the recognition that analyses promising a far better future economic performance were a nonsense. They were based on a faulty understanding of what had happened in the past (ignoring a major reason for the slower growth was the terms of trade fall); they over-estimated the gains from liberalisation (I had to be cautious here, because the literature and data I looked at might have been wrong, although events subsequently confirmed them); the theoretical underpinnings of macroeconomic policy was a nonsense.

My one serious forecast failure was that I did not believe that the policy would be so quickly successful at squeezing out inflation. This was because I did not foresee the breaking of past income and price relativities under the depressed conditions which were to dominate the economy in the late 1980s and early 1990s, together with a ruthless ignoring of equity in the policy framework (something which has still not been fully reversed). Even so, this outcome was consistent with the theoretical model I used in my income distribution work. What I failed to predict was the change in institutional relations.

One important institutional change was the destruction of the traditional public sector to private sector pay relativities in the late 1980s. They had been undermined by the 1982-1984 wage freeze, restored shortly thereafter, and undermined again by the 1988 State Sector Act, reinforced by the 1989 Public Finance Act. Another change, crucial for the disinflation, was the high real exchange rate. It impacted directly by lowering the prices of imports (and also exportables which were consumed locally) thereby directly reducing the consumer price index which was a key linkage in the inflationary spiral mechanism, and indirectly because cheaper imports forced down the price of local producers who competed with them causing unemployment which restrained wage demands

Inevitably the economy was to grow more slowly, although I confess to having been being surprised at the severity of the stagnation which followed the 1987 sharemarket crash – for six successive years, per capita GDP was to fall. Now of course this was not directly predicted from my pre-1981 version of SOME, since there was no major terms of trade fall in this period (they were broadly constant). However, as we saw in the previous section, I had begun to generalise the model. The impact of the terms of trade fall was it affected the profitability of the tradeable sector. Anything else which similarly impacted on export profitability – say a widespread outbreak of foot and mouth disease – would have a similar effect on economic growth. In the late 1980s the shock was the hike in the real exchange rate.

(I was not adverse to its removal of border protection, which also reduces the profitability of import substitution, albeit I wanted a slower pace than occurred and with more support to those restructured. However it was gross stupidity to remove protection while hiking the real exchange rate.)

Faced by a the high exchange rate impacting on profitability and cash flow, businesses in the tradeable sector closed down or slowed down investment (including market development). So export growth slowed down too, while imports rose. Slower economic growth followed.

This did not come to me as an instantaneous insight so much as the SOME paradigm evolved as the economy stagnated. In real time there were alarms and excursions over particular policy issues which can be traced through my various publications, not all of what were irrelevant to the model’s development.

One of the most curious was the mother-of-all-budgets in 1991. The available evidence suggests the economy was moving into the recovery phase of the cycle at the end of 1990. The November 1990 elected National government had instituted a package in December, which unnerved business to the extent that it held over its investment plans aborting the weak recovery and continuing the stagnation. Undismayed the government promised further major cuts of expenditure in its 1991 Budget. It seemed to be an overreaction, a conclusion supported by the graph below which suggested the economy was pushed below its GDP growth track of the 1990s.

I , and a handful of other economists, predicted the economy would contract. It did, but not nearly as much as I had expected. By 1992 the answer was becoming evident. The government had lost fiscal control, with tax revenue falling faster than government spending so the budget deficit increased when it had been expected to decrease. I know, I know, I should have thought of that possibility, but I was not involved in any forecasting team at that time and I relied on the consensus forecast that the deficit would narrow. So the mother-of-all budgets turned into the mother-of-all deficits, saving the economy from an even further serious contraction. (It also enabled the government to claim it had met it promise of halving the unemployment rate. To do this they had to first double the unemployment rate.)

Probably – I have never seen a systematic study – these cuts together with the fiscal measures of the late 1980s had enabled the government accounts to swing into surplus when economic growth recommenced a couple of years later. The surplus has largely continued (it being mainly used to finance government investment). But the cuts impacted on some people harshly. Mike Moore use to say that the government deficit had been replaced by a social deficit.

The SOME paradigm argues that a government surplus may be necessary as a part of keeping the real exchange rate down and exporting profitable. It is related to the two-gap theory in which the internal savings deficit is offset by the external current account deficit. While the theory is not perfect, the sucking of foreign savings through the external account to offset the domestic savings deficiency tends to drive up the exchange rate.

I had conceived of this by the mid 1980s and used to worry the life out of one economist as I mulled over its details. He was the best macro-economist I knew in New Zealand, but sadly his university did not value him, so he returned to Australia where his achievements continued, including becoming the head of department of one of Australia’s most prestigious economic departments. Later my sounding board was Bryan Philpott, and I was cheered when he began to accept the logic of the theory. Like many older economists he had grown up with the traditional Keynesian policy prescription that the government had to run an internal deficit. Keynes largely wrote in the context of a closed economy, whereas SOME is open to international trade. In which case, the Keynesian prescription becomes ‘manage the fiscal stance’ – rather than the traditional monetarist position that the deficit/surplus should be set at zero.

The question of the fiscal stance is not a sidetrack. True, the ASSP does not have a fiscal or monetary component. That it is why it is supply-side. But the alternative – SOME – does, and with that demand-side it is a much more comprehensive account of the economy.

Sometimes one may be aware of the crucial experiment almost at the time it occurs, as I was over the 1974 identification of a change in the economy in the mid to late 1960s, even if I did not know where it would lead. On the other hand, the experiment is not at all understood. For instance the ‘Ruth Cohen’ curiosum was identified in the early 1950s, and hung around for a decade after which it was seen to be an early example of the capital reversing which had so disturbed me in the mid-1970s. So it takes time for a curiosum to be recognised as the ‘crucial experiment’. So while I apologise, one need not be surprised that I cannot recall when the one I am about to relate first happened.

I do know I published it a Listener column in December 1994. I usually let any research findings stew for some time before I write a column. Especially since this was no ‘eureka’ event it probably stewed for a while, although I doubt it was as early as 1993. The most likely identification was when I was completing the final draft of the version of In Stormy Seas which went to the publisher.

I was greatly touched by an historian who read my columns as a means of getting a feel for the events of the day: perhaps others will read through them to trace the development of my thinking (after allowing for the lags discussed in the previous paragraph). However, one must not overestimate their influence. A loud economist said he never read my columns, so the journalist he told reported to me, and then proceeded to explain where I was wrong. On the basis of the account he gave of my views, he was absolutely correct: he had obviously not read my columns.

Even so, it is not unusual to get feedback from economists admiring something I have written, perhaps engaging with the analysis, while on occasions some idea I wrote up – which I thought original, but may not have been – would shortly after enter the economic debate, albeit without attribution. On the other hand some ideas are so revolutionary they get constantly overlooked, in this case for almost a decade, by which time we had more data.

Looking for the Recovery

Since this is a memoir, I might be permitted a diversion. In 1985, when I was Director of the NZIER and just before the floating of the exchange rate, I was visited by some of the OECD delegation on their annual or biennial review of the economy. They asked me what I thought was going on. As we interacted I got the impression they were worried about something– in later I thought it might be that they thought the officials they have talked to were too ideological, but this is only speculation. At the end of the hour they rang for a taxi, and in the small conversation while we waited, I said I was puzzled about what was happening and asked if there was another economy’s experience, that I could look to. There was a silence – I felt that I had made some unpardonable gaffe of international protocol: one does not ask visiting officials questions, they ask you. And after what seemed an interminable period they said but one word ‘Chile’.

So I went and look at the economic literature on Chile. It was useful, but then most international comparisons were. The one thing I remember was it took a darned long time for an economy subject to rapid liberalisation to get back to normal – seven years in the case of Chile.

So in late 1992 I began looking for the signs of a return to growth. And there was the evidence of a cyclic upturn! As I recall I was one of the first economists to mention it in public, using a standard economic term that we were in ‘the recovery stage of the business cycle’, that is the swingup from the bottom or trough. The term ‘recovery’ was seized on by politicians to mean that New Zealand was now in a phase of strong sustainable growth.

Admittedly it looked a long term recovery if you did not think about it too closely since economic growth was strong in 1994 and 1995. I could not see that such growth was sustainable, and took the view that much was a catchup from the contraction caused by National’s 1990 and 1991 fiscal stance. And so it proved to be, slowing down in 1996, followed by a contraction in 1997 in part because the Reserve Bank over-tightened its monetary stance in a response to the Asian crisis.

And so the glee that at last the rogernomics and ruthanasia reforms were working was replaced by the realisation that New Zealand was still subject to cyclical fluctuations and was not growing markedly faster than the rest of the world. But optimism springs eternal, and in the early 2000s the growth spurt was again being attributed to the reforms.

In a way they may be right. The characteristic of the Labour-coalition governments of the early 2000s was that they stuck to the moderate reforms and reversed, where they could, the extreme ones, and did not get too ideological. Even so, New Zealand was at a much lower GDP level relative to the rich world, than it had been when the reforms started.

The Double Step Chart


This is an update on the original graph.

Go to Part II which explains this graph.

Go to top

Paradigms Of New Zealand Economic Growth: a Memoir (part II)

This paper was written in August 2004, for no particular purpose other than to clarify my own ideas.
Part I

Keywords: Growth & Innovation; History of Ideas, Methodology & Philosophy;

Either this kind of aggregate economics appeals or it doesn’t. Personally I belong to both schools. Robert Solow (1957)

PART II
The Double Step Chart
After 1997
Back to Econometric Estimation
Characterising Economic Growth
Standard Growth
Turbo-growth
The Effect of Shocks
Paradigm Conflict

PART I
To 1974: The Aggregate Supply-side Paradigm
The Crucial Experiment of 1974
1975 to 1981
1981 to 1986
The Grand Policy Break and Economic Modelling
The Intervention and Allocation Debate
Leaving the Institute
1986 to 1997
International Comparisons
Bryan Philpott
The Economy After 1985
Looking for the Recovery

The Double Step Chart


This is an update on the original graph.

This is evident from the following graph. Since I cannot remember why I tried this presentational form, it is best if I just show it. While it has been updated since 1994 (and with the addition of extra OECD countries) the basic pattern has not changed. Note it is not too dependent on PPP measures.

The graph sets out the path of New Zealand volume GDP from March year 1955, where it is indexed to 1000. Over this New Zealand GDP path is superimposed three OECD GDP paths. The first, on the left of the chart, is set so that OECD GDP at the same 1000 in the March 1955 year. The middle path has the OECD GDP set at 820 in the March 1955 year, that is 18 percent lower than the first OECD path. The third path, on the right, has the OECD GDP set at 730 in the March 1955 year, or 11 percent lower than the middle path.

The graph does not challenge the conventional wisdom’s notion that the relative level of NZ GDP per capita (measured the usual way) fell over the post war period relative to the OECD as a whole. What it challenges is that this fall was continuous, incrementally every year. Rather, in two thirds of the years – perhaps more – the New Zealand economy grew at much the same rate as the rest of the OECD. The slowing down occurred in two transition periods: 1966-1977 and 1986-1993. The effect was like twice dropping a step on the ladder, rather than slithering down it. Moreover each step down is associated with a shock which we recognise as the terms of trade collapse of 1966, and the real exchange rate hike of 1985. With minor (cyclical) variations, this is a pattern of OECD growth, stagnation after shock, OECD growth, stagnation after shock, OECD growth.

What I want to do here is look at the question of how the ASSP might explain the graph. This is a very hard question to answer for someone who has a superior SOME paradigm (in the methodological sense of fully incorporating the inferior ASSP paradigm). It is like having chunks of one’s tool kit locked away, or explaining the path of a satellite using the Ptolemaic system..

One solution is to deny the graph, or ignore it. But confronted with the graph, how might the ASSP deal with it? The only useful way I can think of – there are not a lot of degrees of freedom in the ASSP – is that some or all of the labour, capital or technical progress stopped growing or contracted during the transition periods. If that is correct, then in principle they can measure how much of each, by looking at the five individual periods separately, rather than the whole period.

Of course having done that, the next question is why those quantities contracted. Any answer involves looking at the macroeconomic events of the economy at the time, which pushes one towards the SOME, just as it did to me decades ago.

In particular the graph makes plain the absurdity of many of the standard explanations which are used by the conventional wisdom to justify New Zealand’s slow growth rate. It hardly suggests New Zealand is too small or too distant. Did New Zealand get smaller and or more distant between 1966 and 1977 and 1985 and 1994? What about the theory, popular in the early years of the reforms, that it was excessive intervention ‘what done it’. Did intervention increase during the transition periods, and what about the 1982 to 1984 period when intervention did increase (the wage-price freeze) and there is no slower growth rate transition. (This reinforces my earlier observation that if intervention was the problem, how come New Zealand grew so spectacularly in the 1930s and 1940s when interventions were being increased.)

And if a reduction in corporate tax (or whatever is one’s pet policy solution) will accelerate economic growth, was corporate taxation (or whatever) raised at the beginning of the two transition periods and lowered at each’s end? It took me a long time to realise that a lot of the unattached theories which surround the ASSP are refuted – at least in the crude form they are generally presented – by this double step down graph. Already knowing they were inadequate I did not look for such a simple demonstration.

I used the graph twice in In Stormy Seas but with hindsight I did not make enough of it, perhaps because it was such a late addition to the book I had not fully grasped its significance. In any case I needed more years of data to understand it properly

After 1997

I turned away from extending SOME after the publication of In Stormy Seas, and put my effort into other research areas. Perhaps there was an intellectual exhaustion, perhaps the economy was not doing anything interesting. Certainly the conventional wisdom was not, so there was little spur to improve the paradigm.

I monitored the economy, occasionally updating the double step graph and writing the story up. The one extension to SOME was the realisation that individual country comparisons were relevant, although even then this was not such an innovation since I had already done some sectoral comparisons in the supply-side chapter of In Stormy Seas . I had been interested in Australian-New Zealand comparisons since my visit there in 1987, and did a detailed policy comparison, published in early 1996, which suggested Australia’s less extremist policy reform resulted in a better economic performance (and showed how constitutional arrangements affected policy choice). The theme was taken up by other New Zealand economists somewhat later without any acknowledgement of this earlier work, which I thought discourteous to my co-author, Australian Rolf Gerritsen.

I added other quantitative comparisons of country performance, albeit without the same close policy consideration What they invariably showed was that New Zealand’s tradeable sector had done poorly in comparison to the others, which had better export performance and less imports (measured by import penetration), a fact which would be unintelligible to an aggregate commodity paradigm such as ASSP, but was predicted by SOME.

But I did not do a lot new for about six years.

I am not sure why I came out of hibernation. One factor may have been when Alan Bollard became its Secretary, to his credit, he insisted that the Treasury formalise their paradigm. Reading their research papers, led me to think about SOME again. Additionally, the Ministry of Economic Development asked me in early 2004 to provide a brief history of New Zealand’s economic growth, weighted towards recent events. I did not set out the formal SOME, but I used it in the discussion and had to think about it again as a part of the presentation.

Back to Econometric Estimation

I then noticed I had made an interesting methodological short-cut, understandable at the time, but no longer necessary. In order to gauge the effect of the terms of trade and the real exchange rate I had concentrated on two obvious major negative shocks. But there were minor shocks, and sometimes they were positive ones. Why not estimate the impact econometrically?

I had mucked around with some econometric estimation in about 1990. It is not reported in In Stormy Seas because I had ended up with a thoroughly confusing lag structure, and in any case the data series was relatively short and would not have had enough of the post 1985 shock to get a good bind. A decade-and-a-half later there was additional data, and an econometric technique called co-integration which cut through the lag problem. So with the help of Les Oxley, professor of economics at the University of Canterbury, I tried it.

Of course the econometrics simplified SOME. It assumed that the ratio of New Zealand GDP to OECD GDP was a function of the profitability of the export sector, which is algebraically equivalent to a combination of the terms of trade and the real exchange rate. What it says is that if these two variables remain constant New Zealand will grow at the same rate as the rest of the OECD (business cycles aside).

Blow me down, the econometrics worked. (Oh, me of little faith.) In summary a 1 percent long run fall in the terms of trade reduces (production side) GDP by .7 percent (and income side GDP by 1 percent) in the long run, while a 1 percent long run rise in the real exchange rate in reduces GDP (measured on either side) by .3 percent in the long run. (To my astonishment when reading my 1982 paper I observe that I had estimated the latter figure – i.e. .3 percent – all those years ago using a quite different method. It may be a coincidence but I need to go back and think about it.)

With these more precise estimates I could explore some aspects of the postwar economy which hitherto had not been possible. Among the new refinements were:

1. It is possible that there is a two step process in the transition from 1966 to 1977. You just can see it in the graph. I had tended to discount it, treating the 1972-1973 world commodity boom as a temporary shock. It does not materially change the model.

2. It appears part of the lift in the late 1990s and early 2000s may be due to a secular (i.e. long term) recovery in the terms of trade. Again you can see it in the graph. I have yet to study why that happened, but I should not be surprised if the Uruguay Round was a factor, which has implications for the effect of the much more favourable Doha Round on economic performance. Where do international trade agreements come into the ASSP? (Another factor may have been the falling price of computers, as a result of the spectacular rate of technical change. Again where does that come in the ASSP?)

3. Because I focussed on big shocks I completely failed to pick up that there had been a rising real exchange rate in the 1950s and 1960s which slowed down New Zealand’s growth rate. Again you can just see it in the graph, in that New Zealand was growing slightly slower than the OECD. (I was aware of this but the effect was small, and I attribute it in part to poor measurement of service growth, a hypothesis I have yet to abandon.) On the other hand the real exchange rate fell a little in the 1970s and that eased back the impact of the terms of trade fall. You cant see it in the graph because it is masked by the terms of trade transition. The reason I did not pick up the real exchange rate effects during the early part of the postwar era was partly because I was focusing on major shocks, but also because I graphed the series on a linear rather than log linear scale. Go on, look at it on page 87 of In Stormy Seas – botheration! I had discounted the real exchange rate’s importance before 1985, and I should not have.

This last finding led to an even more astonishing one. When I looked at the whole of the post-war era, I found that real exchange rate had a bigger overall impact than the terms of trade on of New Zealand’s GDP. Although the terms of trade impact is about double the real exchange rate for the same change, the real exchange rate deterioration over the period has been more than double the terms of trade deterioration.

Now this has an important, and for me not entirely expected, policy implication. Following the identification of the 1966 terms of trade shock, I had implicitly assumed that the deterioration in the New Zealand relativity was largely out of New Zealand’s hands for while we can have a little influence of the price on some commodities – by not pushing too much on the world market – generally our export and import prices are set overseas by factors outside New Zealand’s control.

However the real exchange rate is more subject to local influence, although it is not easy to control. It is not just a matter of setting the nominal exchange rate, since internal inflation may offset the change. Nevertheless the real exchange rate is more controllable than the terms of trade. The policy implication is that New Zealand’s poor growth performance was far more a matter of macroeconomic management than I had assumed. Had we paid more attention to it we could have done better. I can hear Bryan Philpott chuckling away at this conclusion.

Characterising Economic Growth

We can observe two sorts of growth patterns among rich OECD countries: standard growth and turbo-growth. But we need to take into responses to shocks into consideration..

Standard Growth

One of the least remarked features of the modern growth patterns is that most of the top rich countries grow at roughly the same rate, with their per capita PPP adjusted GDPs moving along like a pack of runners bunched together. Some are at the front of the bunch, some at in the middle, some at the back. While there is some over-taking and falling behind, basically the bunch moves at the same broad rate.

We cannot even be sure of each runner’s positions in the bunch, because the statistical measures are not particularly accurate. We may have suspicions to explain some of the placings: this country may use more of its population in the workforce, that country’s workforce may work fewer hours than average, this seems to have more capital, that has more resources. When we try to measure these effects we end up in statistical difficulties and uncertainties.

How can we explain this bunching phenomenon? The ASSP says hardly anything, but let me go back to Joan Robinson’s model of technology as blueprints, an approach that I have had a revived interest in, following conversations with Ken Carlaw, at the University of Canterbury, who with Dick Lipsey and Carl Bekar is doing some really interesting thinking about technology in economic growth (which also provides a critique of the ASSP). I wont go into it all here in any detail – watch in the future how it changes my view – but here is my interpretation of a central idea. Suppose the technology blueprints are widely available so that all rich countries have access to them (at a low cost, for technology royalties are generally low compared to the national returns they generate – often because they lower prices). If ‘technology’ is the major determinant of economic growth, and allowing for the labour force and capital stock to be affected by migration and international capital flows – one would expect the bunching we observe among countries with well trained labour forces and favourable institutional arrangements.

There is a further feature of the Carlaw et al approach which attracts me. The ASSP sees technological progress mysteriously increasing over time, with no explanation as to how that happens. However Carlaw et al are more careful. They see the stock of technology blueprints increasing. This is also mysterious, but there is a substantial literature in industry economics which describes much of the process, so the mystery is shifted to a lower level, rather than the hand-waving of the ASSP.

Since these technologies are continually being applied, economic growth is really about numerous small increments, each lifting the economy to a slightly higher level of production. But as in quantum mechanics, the jerky increases at the micro-level appear smooth at the macro-level.

Carlaw et al go a step further with the notion of General Purpose Technologies (GPTs), that is very powerful technologies which dramatically open up the possibilities of numerous new blueprints which can be applied in a variety of situations. Examples are electricity and the silicon chip. They think there are a not of lot of GPTs over the entirety of the human history – although many of them have been in the last couple of centuries of economic growth. In the long run GPTs lift output by a significant step, but in the short run, because it takes time to explore all their implications – to create all the new blueprints – their sequential introduction gives the impression of smoothness. When the current GPTs have worked their way through and if there are no new ones, economic growth will largely come to a halt.

Now where GPTs come from – and what is the next one – is still mysterious. But the model pushes the mystery a bit further back, and it does have some policy implications which come out of the model rather than are arbitrarily attached. For instance: since most technology blueprints are generated overseas, a major policy issue is international technology transfer. (This is not incompatible with the ASSP, but because it is treated as a model of a closed economy, the point is overlooked, and the rhetoric – and, I’m afraid, policy – focuses on domestically produced technology (i.e. the creation of blueprints) and downplays the international dimension (their import and local utilisation).

Turbo-growth

While the pattern of bunching economies predominates there are a few shooting stars – economies that grow much faster than the typical OECD rich one. Examples include Germany in the 1950s, post-war Japan up to 1990, Ireland in the 1990s, and the Asian Tigers in the 1980s and 1990s. A feature of the growth is that the economy starts off well below the OECD rich bunch and the growth comes to an end when that economy joins them. There is no example of a shooting star which has overshot.

Turbo-growth involves economies which are technologically backward but have conditions which enable them to adopt the top-of-the line technologies used by the rich countries. Those conditions include appropriate institutional arrangements, a supply of underutilised labour (Asian agriculture or the Irish unemployed) or from migration (Germany and Ireland), which has the appropriate set of technical skills, and a supply of financial capital (from international capital markets or high domestic savings). Additionally there must be markets where they can sell the additional output. It is rare that they can rely upon their internal markets – that they can bootstrap – so exporting plays an important role especially if the economy is small or specialised. It is the application of top-of the-line technologies which are key and once they are fully utilised and the economy joins the rich bunch, the turbo-growth ceases and it grows at roughly the same rate as the bunch (although there may be difficulties adjusting to this slower growth as we saw with Japan in the 1990s).

Every one wants turbo-growth so there is much rhetoric about it. But the conditions for it are rather special and not available to the majority of rich countries because they already have the technologies, nor to poor countries because they lack the institutions and sufficient of the technologically adept labour force.

Is New Zealand capable of turbo-growth? It has no obvious reserves of labour. (It is not obvious that migration would be a source in the way it was for West Germany from displaced East Germans and Ireland from returning diaspora.) Perhaps a half-turbo could come from upgrading New Zealand’s technology to top-of the line, except where is it not? (Management?) It is also possible that New Zealand has the wrong industry mix, but we dont know which. After all, New Zealand may be behind the bunch because of measurement error rather than something inherently wrong. WE JUST DONT KNOW.

This reflection on turbo-growth raises the issue as to what growth enhancing policies are about? The conventional wisdom’s rhetoric says their purpose is to accelerate growth, but the last few pages suggest that is not particularly practical for a rich country.

There is a simpler explanation of the role of these policies. Their purpose is not to lift the growth rate, but to lift output – they are about progressing how far the car has gone, not making it faster. They sustain the current (or, more precisely, rich OECD) growth rate, rather than accelerate it. The policy actions enable the adoption of the new technologies that are becoming available or tackle the bottlenecks the growth generates where there is no market mechanism to resolve it optimally (i.e. transport congestion). While such an objective is less grand than the promise of faster growth, it is more realistic. Strip away policies (and advocated policies) which are primarily distributional, and the vast majority of new policies being implemented in a well functioning economy are dealing with new technologies or the consequences of growth which market responses cannot resolve.

The ACCP says that technical progress speeds the car along at some natural rate, and it is possible to take policy measures which make it go faster. Why the car goes at this natural speed at all is a mystery, and so largely is what the additional petrol which accelerates it.

On the other hand SOME (although it would be wrong to confine this account solely to the SOME paradigm) says the petrol that determines the speed is the newly available technologies (in the blueprint sense). For most cars that characterise the rich countries, there is a maximum amount of available petrol, so there is a maximum speed. The accelerator foot is already down on the floor and the car cant go any faster. However some cars have additional petrol because they have not used up all that has become available in the past (they have underutilised technologies), so they experience turbo-growth, until they use up their petrol reserves (the underutilised technologies). Since those without reserves all get the same amount of petrol, they all drive at roughly the same speed – which gives the bunching we observe.

The Effect of Shocks

Even if we omit technological change, every economy experiences an unremitting flow of shocks. Fortunately most are small, and they average out. Sometimes they are larger, but transient as when an important market goes through a cyclical fluctuation. (This paper’s account has largely ignored the business cycle although in In Stormy Seas it plays an integral role which could be explained in a longer paper.) However, occasionally an economy experiences a major external shock, of which New Zealand’s 1966 terms of trade collapse is a very good example.

The shocks change the relative profitability, which determines the choice of the blueprints which are applied. A fall in profitability usually means a switch of production techniques and change in the pattern of production. This involves a setback in the growth process as firms have to learn to use the new technologies. Moreover, they are doing so with constrained cash flow, which is not only used to fund new capital, but the upgrading of the skills of the work force and a host of other things such as market development which are integral to technology implementation.

In terms of the car analogy of the previous subsection, it is like getting a puncture. It slows you down and it takes time to change the tyre. However the economy does not really save any petrol (that is miss out any going technologies) from the experience, so when it gets going again it follows behind, unable to catch up with the bunch. But it continues to go at the same speed as the bunch.

When I first began developing this paradigm I assumed that there would be a permanent slowdown (which, incidentally, caused some of my confusion with the econometrics in the 1990s). However it is clear from the two-step graph (and the cointegration results) that once the transition to the new profitability structure is completed the economy seems to grow at broadly the same rate.

The first draft of this paper went on to discuss various ways in which the Carlaw et al approach could be incorporated into this transition. I’ve decided not to include it in the final draft, because my views are not adequately formed. One day I will go back and recall that perhaps the most important contribution of this paper to SOME was the material I have left out, because it began getting me to think about the problem. But at the moment it is just too early to tell.

Paradigm Conflict

The visiting economist from Mars would be very puzzled why the ASSP was so popular given its obvious limitations. He or she would acknowledge that it seemed seductively simple to non-economists who assume that the economists’ concepts that underpin it are deeper than they are. But why do economists hang on to it?

I, too, have puzzled over this and have come to the conclusion that the ASSP’s greatest merit is that because it is so vacuous it is does not threaten the policy agenda of the conventional wisdom. Because it has no macroeconomics, it does not challenge their macroeconomic policies; because it has no microeconomics it does not challenge their microeconomics; because it is empirically vague it does not force a consideration of whether past policies were less than optimal.

Any paradigm has to protect itself from challenge. Hence the neutralisation of Bryan Philpott, but this is an example of the wider phenomenon in which the conventional wisdom ignores alternative paradigms. Almost every bibliography of an ASSP paper is bereft of New Zealand generated research other than that which is in the ASSP tradition. The colonial cringe ensures the bibliography is stacked with irrelevant papers from overseas. But of critiques there is nary a reference.

Ignoring such research means the ASSP does not engage with it, and therefore never opens itself to the critical improvement which is central to scientific progress. That is why the ASSP is a stagnating paradigm, unable to generate any new insights or make new predictions about the real world. On the other hand, were it to engage with its critics – and the real world – it would have to be radically transformed.

I do not know whether the SOME model is ultimately correct. Actually I do because, as every Popperian researcher knows, it will be one day be replaced by a better paradigm. All one can say is that it addresses many of the issues which the ASSP ignores and – as this memoir has demonstrated – it has been an open one, evolving as it has engaged with other paradigms and with the real world. Hopefully it will continue to do so.

Go to top

Flavoured Alcoholic Beverages and Reducing Teenage Drinking Harm

Submission to 2004 Youth Parliament (some amendments following the presentation on 17 August, 2004).

Keywords: Health; Regulation & Taxation;

0. Introduction

0.1. My name is Brian Easton. I hold degrees, including a D.Sc., from the University of Canterbury in mathematics and economics, and from Victoria University of Wellington in economics. I am a Fellow of the Royal Statistical Society, a Charted Statistician, and hold university positions at the University of Otago, Victoria University of Wellington, and Auckland University of Technology, where I am an adjunct professor at the Institute of Public Policy.

0.2. I have considerable experience in research, analysis, teaching, and writing in the areas of economics, social statistics and public policy. Particularly relevant for this submission I have a long record of the research and public policy analysis on alcohol consumption and other drugs. I have been on the International Working Party which prepared the WHO published International Guidelines for Estimating the Costs of Substance Abuse. (2.ed, 2002) I have written he most authoritative study of the social costs of alcohol and tobacco in New Zealand The Social Costs of Tobacco Use and Alcohol Misuse (1997) In 2002 I prepared the report Taxing Harm: Modernising Alcohol Excise Duties for the Alcohol Advisory Council, some of which’s recommendations were implemented in May 2003, and which is discussed further below.

0.3. I have been asked to prepare a brief on whether the excise duty on Flavoured Alcoholic Beverages (FABs a.k.a Alcopops) should be increased. (Section 3)

0.4 In order to do this properly I have set out my understanding of public policy towards alcohol consumption (Section 1), explained how my Taxing Harm report fits into this context (Section 3), and also briefly looked at alternatives policy options (Section 5). The focus of the paper is on teenage drinking (Section 2).

0.5 My conclusion is that while an across-the-board increase of excise duty is likely to reduce drinking harm, increasing taxation on FABs is unlikely to do so. In regard to the problem of teenage drinking I suggest there may be other more effective policy options. (Section 6.)

1. Public Policy Towards Alcohol Consumption: the Context

1.1 My understanding of the current public policy framework towards alcohol consumption is that it treats alcohol consumed in moderation as a pleasurable social activity which is socially benign like most other consumption. However, it recognises that some alcohol consumption can be socially damaging. Public policy aims to minimize the potentially harmful consumption with the least impact on benign consumption as possible. A number of policy instruments including education, legal proscription and regulation, and taxation are applied. Typically they are targeted on particular harmful consumption. However alcohol specific taxation is not a well targeted policy instrument. It is intended to reduce the harm on which no other policy instrument can be targeted, but in doing so it also reduces benign consumption.

(1.2 There is a case that some alcohol consumption can be beneficial. The research evidence suggests any benefits are for very low levels of consumption, and are small in comparison to the harm from excessive drinking. Probably the most important benefit is for those with a degree of heart disease. This only applies to older men and women, so it is of little relevance to the young. Mild benefits are not uncommon for many other acts of private consumption (e.g. eating food prevents starvation), but the general approach of public policy is not to take any specific action to promote such consumption, other than use education to enlighten consumers, and stress the benefits of moderation where it is necessary.)

1.3 A particular issue is that people have to learn to drink safely. Under the most favourable circumstances, the socialisation of the young into sensible drinking is bound to be difficult for most, and hazardous for some. This is not because they are ‘irrational’ but because the process of socialisation involves complex tasks in a context in which the body’s physiology and the social environments are changing. It is compounded for this generation by their elders, who having grown up in a much more restrictive drinking environment, not always being able to give the younger generation the guidance and support which is normal in the socialisation process, nor of always setting a good example.

2. Teenage Drinking Practices

2.1 While every society with a liberal approach to liquor will have teenage drinking problems, New Zealand seems to be facing a rising one. There is a public awareness of the problem but there has been little additional public policy response.

2.2 The annual Auckland surveys (the longest continuous set we have) show that the average number of drinks consumed on one occasion among 14 to 19 year olds increased from 3 to 4 in 1990 to 5 to 6 drinks in 1999. The rise was particular strong at the younger end, with the 14 to 17 year olds increasing from 2 to 3 drinks in 1990 to 5 to 6 in 1999. (In this context a ‘drink’ is equivalent to a standard stubby of beer, or 15g of alcohol. A ‘standard drink’ is only 10g of alcohol, so a stubby is 1.5 standard drinks.)

2.3 The National Alcohol Survey found that the average quantity of ethanol consumed by 14 to 17 year olds doubled between 1995 and 2000. It also rose for 18 to 19 year olds, but fell or was much the same for older age groups. A similar pattern applies for frequency of drinking (occasions per year). The survey also found that the 14 to 19 year olds were consuming more over time, in contrast to the older age groups whose rate had not changed much over the five years.

2.4 There are no long term series but currently over a third of 14 to 17 year olds consider themselves ‘heavy drinkers’. The National Survey found that 7 percent of 14 to 15 year old males, 25 percent of 16-17 year old males and 40 percent of 18-19 year old males were involved in a session of at least 6 standard drinks at least once a week. The latter proportion was more than for 20 to 24 year olds, and the 16-17 year old proportion more than occurs for those over 25 years old. The same patterns apply for females, except their levels are slightly lower (7, 22, and 28 percent).

2.5 These trends are reinforced by the evidence that the age of first drinking seems to be lowering, although the surveys were not well designed to measure this. It seems that the earlier the age of onset of drinking the more likely the young person is to be involved in heavy drinking in later years.

2.7 While heavy drinking is associated with harm, it is more difficult to measure the actual harm that occurs. Typically the data is not collected by association with alcohol, so that it is difficult to draw rigorous conclusions.

2.8 In summary there has been rising drinking among teenagers in the 1990s, older teenagers appear to be at least as prone to heavy drinking as young adults and, because they are less experienced, they are likely to be in more harm generating situations.

2.8 However, the same surveys show that most harmful drinking occurs in the 18 to 26 year old group. This submission does not directly address the problem of young adult harmful drinking, but it notes that if teenagers learn appropriate drinking, they are less likely to drink harmfully when they are 18 to 26 years. On the other hand, were drinking among young adults less harmful, then they would set a better example for younger drinkers. So bad drinking habits in both groups have to be addressed.

3. The Taxing Harm Report

3.1 My report, Taxing Harm: Modernising Alcohol Excise Duties, was commissioned in 2002 by the Alcohol Liquor Advisory Council as a review public policy on the taxation of alcohol. The following review of the report focusses on those parts concerned with reducing harm from teenage drinking.

3.2 Additional taxation on alcoholic beverages raises prices, which deters some drinking. Some of the deterred drinking will be benign but some will be (potentially) harmful. Thus public policy has to trade-off reductions in benign drinking which represent a social loss, from reductions in harmful drinking which represent a social gain. That is the reason that economists argue that taxation should be the policy instrument of last resort, after all other effective instruments are properly targeted.

(3.3. For instance, harm from alcohol-induced road accidents could be reduced by punitively high excise taxes on alcohol. However that would discourage drinking which was not related to road accidents. A more effective strategy is heavy penalties for drink-driving and effective enforcement.)

3.4 The research evidence suggests that biggest reductions in harm from rising alcohol prices are likely to arise from
– reduced teenage consumption;
– inhibiting moderate and heavy drinkers becoming very heavy drinkers, and
– reduced additional drinking in a session.

3.5 The report suggested the relevant price target was the unit cost of absolute alcohol (i.e the ethanol in the alcoholic beverage). This supports the approach where excise duty is levied on ethanol content, irrespective of the source of the alcohol. The effect of such a tax is to raise the cost of cheap beverages relative to expensive ones. For instance the current excise duty increases the price of a bottle of wine by about $2.00 irrespective of whether the wine costs $10 a bottle or $100 a bottle. Since each contains the same amount of alcohol, each has the same potential to do harm, and so the levy is the same.

3.6 At the time of the report, the cost of light spirits – spirits based drinks which are 23 percent absolute alcohol by volume – assessed by unit costs of ethanol, was much lower than for other sources of ethanol. It was possible for as little as $8.00 to purchase 23 standard drinks, enough to kill a person – sadly on least two cases it did. Anecdote had it that light spirits was a significant source of ethanol for those teenagers who wanted to consume to harmful excess rather participate in socially benign drinking.

3.7 When I examined the reasons for the low cost of light spirits, I found a major factor was some anomalies in the taxation system. I recommended these be eliminated. In May 2003 the government removed the anomalies, which doubled the cost of the light spirits. As a result light spirits are no longer attractive to those who simply wanted to get drunk, and their demand fell substantially. I am told that they are no longer available.

3.8 Of course that has not stopped those who want to get drunk. Rather they have switched to other sources of alcohol. However, because the other sources are more expensive, teenagers – in particular – are likely to purchase less ethanol and get drunk less often.

(3.9 A collateral effect of the government removing the tax anomalies which favoured light spirits was that excise taxation of fortified wines (such as sherry) and liqueurs was also raised. Apparently the fall-off in consumption was much smaller, consistent with the notion that consumers of these other forms of alcohol were not simply purchasing ethanol, that they were purchasing less per drinking session, and that being older they were not as price sensitive.)

4 Flavoured Alcoholic Beverages

4.1 Favoured Alcoholic Beverages (FABs) are typically spirits based drinks with added flavour which come in containers similar to beer (i.e. bottles and cans) and which have a similar level of absolute alcohol per unit volume (4 to 8%). (they are also called ready-to-drink or RTDs).

4.2 When I looked at the price of FABs measured by the cost ethanol I found them similar to, and not markedly below that of, beer in similar containers. I found no tax anomaly which favoured FABs.

4.3 Suppose a higher excise duty was placed upon FABs relative to beer. (I assume it would be levied on the basis of it being a spirit.) My conclusion is that higher priced FABs would result in their drinkers switching to other (now relatively cheaper) alcohol products. Because FABs tend to be sweeter than beer, we might also expect breweries to create sweeter beers, while it seems likely that wine producers would provide a diluted sweet wine to fill the FAB niche. In summary, I concluded on that raising the excise duty only on FABs would not significantly reduce the consumption of ethanol nor alcohol harm, because consumers would switch to cheaper drinks.

4.4. I was aware of the anecdotal argument that FABs are particularly seductive to new drinkers (especially young women) because of their sweetness. Whatever the truth of this argument, the introduction of sweet light wines and beers would mean that there would be comparably seductive drinks. I add that it is not obvious that a particular type of beverage which introduces the young to drinking is necessarily a bad thing. The test has to be whether it causes more harm than the alternatives. There is little rigorous evidence to support such a conclusion.

4.5 An alternative strategy would be to raise excise taxation on all alcohol, including FABs. This would reduce alcohol induced harm through reductions in consumption, but some of those reductions would be of benign consumption.

(4.6 I would personally support a hike in excise duties on alcohol, not only to reduce harm but because the extra revenue could be used for socially useful public expenditure (say more spending on education) or personal tax cuts. Because of the pattern of drinking – which is concentrated in particular small groups – over half the population, perhaps three quarters, would benefit from a hike in alcohol excise, despite having to pay more for their beverages and cutting back on consumption, providing the additional revenue is used effectively.)

5. Alternative Policies to Reduce Harm from Teenage Alcohol Consumption

5.1 Nevertheless we have a teenage drinking problem. Even if raising the price of FABs will not reduce it, we might consider what other measures we might take to reduce harmful drinking while enabling teenagers to learn how to drink. The following are some frequently proposed ones:

5.2 More public and school education, although we need to be careful, because there is a tendency to propose education as a solution to everything, without much attention to whether the program is effective.

5.3 Advertising is a sort of education. There is much dispute over whether advertising has increased harmful alcohol consumption. Those who argue it does not, say that since alcohol is just about like any other commodity, it should be advertised so people can make better choices. Those who argue it does, say that the advertising encourages people to consume more. (There are some restrictions on advertising which exclude the most blatant encouragements, especially those which might encourage harmful drinking.) Obviously the young are more likely to be influenced by any advertisements, and we might be more restrictive where they may see them although, other than eliminating alcohol advertisements for teenage-only programs, it is hard to know how to do this without banning all advertisements.

5.4 Raising the general level of alcohol excise duties (see para 4.5). But it would impact on benign consumption of alcohol by adults and teenagers.

5.5 Raising the ‘drinking age’. This is often advocated, although not always in an informed way. Currently a person who is under 18 has various restrictions on where they may drink, whether they may be on a licenced premise, and they may not purchase liquor. The argument for a higher drinking age is the ‘shadow’, the group below the legal age who break any law. (What is a group of friends of 17 and 18 year olds to do? Stay out of pubs? Breakup?) The main argument for 18 is that it is the minimum voting age. There is little evidence that when the legal age of purchase was reduced there was any acceleration in the upward trend of youth drinking, although it may be too early to tell. (Note that a phased approach by age to drinking to reflect the stages of learning to drink sensibly makes public policy sense in terms of the young learning to drink.)

5.6 Better enforcement of the law. It is argued the police do not put in enough effort policing underage illegal drinking in public places. The police say they dont have enough resources, and they have higher priorities.

5.7 The restrictions on drinking in public are greater than drinking in private situations – say parties in private homes. Should they not be the same?

5.8 Currently we restrict supply to under 18s, by not allowing them to purchase liquor. However others can do it on their behalf. The law could be changed so that anyone who supplies an underage drinker – seller (who are already prohibited), parent or guardian, or someone else, say an over age friend – is responsible for any harm the underage drinker causes as a result of that drinking, including being drunk. I am in favour of this change, not because it would have a lot of such suppliers jailed, but because it would bring home to people that they must take responsibility for the act of supply alcohol to a person who is judged to be not yet fully competent to consume it. (I would also have a less onerous, but parallel, law about supplying alcohol to persons over the age of 18 who is drunk.)

5.9 My report Taxing Harm recommended eliminating the excise duty on alcoholic beverages with an ethanol content below 2.5 percent, thus making them more attractive to consumers by their greater cheapness. Experts told me that one would ‘drown’ before getting inebriated on such diluted alcohol.

5.10 While the law is important, actions by other groups in the community are also important. Schools which regulate liquor usage before and after school events are example. Do all schools have good practices? Are there any other institutions which should take a similar responsibility? (For instance should functions – some university fresher events sometimes do – offer a fixed entrance fee, and allow those there to drink as much as they can?).

5.11 The previous two paragraphs are illustrative of a more general proposition. We cannot markedly reduce harmful teenage drinking unless their elders set a good example.

6. Conclusion

6.1 Learning good drinking habits is a challenge for the young, made more difficult because not all their elders have good drinking habits.

6.2 There is evidence of rising teenage harmful drinking.

6.3. Even if Flavoured Alcohol Beverages are important in teenage drinking, it is not obvious that proscribing them or raising excise duty on them will reduce harm from teenage drinking, because teenagers are likely to switch to substitutes.

6.4 Raising excise duties on all alcohol is likely to reduce some harmful drinking, but it will also reduce some benign drinking.

6.5 There are other ways of reducing harmful teenage drinking. Among those proposed are the following (although they may not all be helpful):

(i) More public and school education (para 5.2)

(ii) Advertising restrictions (para 5.3)

(iii) Higher excise duties on all alcohol (para 5.4)

(iv) Raising the drinking age (para 5.5)

(v) Better enforcement of the law (para 5.6)

(vi) Extending the law in regard to drinking in public places to drinking in private places (para 5.7)

(vii) Placing a legal responsibility on all those who supply under age drinkers to ensure that the drinking should not be harmful (para 5.8)

(viii) Making low ethanol content drinks more price attractive by eliminating excise duty for those with an ethanol content of 2.5 percent.

(ix) Institutions which are involved with teenagers should ensure that the drinking environments do not promote harmful drinking (para 5.10)

(x) Elders need to set a good example by reducing their harmful drinking (para 5.11)

Go to top

Russian Lessons

The Economic Prognosis is Not Good for the Latest Russian Revolution
Listener: 27 January, 1996

Keywords: Political Economy & History;

Recently economist Rufus Dawe described himself, in the National Business Review, as the Trotsky of the rogernomics revolution. Who he had in mind as the Lenin and the Stalin of rogernomics is unclear. Trotsky said of Stalin that his rise to power was evidence of the mediocrity of the system.

Yet perhaps there is a truth in Mr Dawe’s parallel. A small minority (the bolsheviks) captured the power of the state, without a mandate, destroying the possibility of a social democracy (the mensheviks, who were in a majority of the revolutionaries), instituting repression against dissidents, with a mediocrity of management, and not very competent economic policies.

Eight decades later the Russians are still struggling with the consequences of their revolution. Despite the destruction of the Soviet Empire, and the collapse of the Communist Party monopoly, the December 1995 elections gave the Russian CP a fifth of the vote (double that of the previous election) and a third of the seats in parliament, making them the largest single party. Moreover, and unlike the ex-communist parties of Central European states which were part of the Soviet bloc, the Russian one is not reconstructed. This turn around in the Russian CP’s fate is extraordinary. A few years ago the collapse of communism was trumpeted; today there are anxious editorials about its resurgence.

I am not surprised. I visited the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe shortly after the collapse, and was struck by the naivety over the economic transformation required to create a liberal market democracy. The uncritical assumption was the end of “their” economic system (whatever that was), reflected the triumph of “our” system (whatever that was). It does not seem to be turning out that way.

The West did not help the transition. That was partly because the obvious means of assisting the transformation could not happen. Recall the Marshall Plan, that massive transfer of American funds to Western Europe immediately after the war. No such transfer was possible for the far more ruined Soviet bloc.

The Soviet Empire had become economically bankrupt, in major part because of it financing of the arms race against the US. While the US may not be bankrupt, it is teetering on the edge of a major economic catastrophe because their contribution to the arms race was funded by government borrowing which led to accumulating US government debt. (As I write Clinton and Gringrich are locked in a struggle of how to haul back that deficit and debt.) The US simply did not have the where-with-all to repeat its generosity.

Instead the catch cry was “privatization” of the state assets. All shades of investors from the West descended upon the ex-communist states to “assist” them. I met a number, many of whom struck me as shysters, con-men, and frauds. They teamed up with as unsavoury people within the countries (many of whom had only been a little earlier stalwarts of the local Communist Party). Some of the foreign and local investors did well enough out of the transfer of the assets into private (i.e. their) hands, but there is no evidence the economies did as well. Most contracted, increasing the hardship which had led to the collapse of the previous regimes, while revealing unemployment for the first time. Of course there are people better off under the new regime, but as a general rule in most economies the average person is materially poorer than they were at the time of the collapse.

It was not only economic factors which brought about the collapse. The Soviet Union suffered a moral bankruptcy too. We can argue whether it was inevitable that the high ideals of the founders of communism would inevitably crumble in the political regime in which they were implemented. But crumble they did, and in the end there was very little to say positively about the communist party leadership. So what did the West do? It sent shysters, con-men and frauds who linked up with people of as little morality.

No wonder a substantial proportion of the Russian people, and in some of the satellites, are returning to the residual of the Communist Party. Where else are they to go: the fascists, the super-nationalists?

The economic (and therefore, probably, the political) prognosis is not good. Nor should a New Zealander be surprised. Our transition from a lesser level of intervention to a more open market economy has been slow and painful enough. Their required transformation is much greater. When I mentioned our experiences to those in the ex-communist countries, there were too many people making fast – and often dishonest – bucks for such cautions to be given any weight.

Trotskyism rejects the evolutionary parliamentary road of the ballot box as illusory. I am more sanguine. But it is a slow path, with set-backs as well as progress. If we have a role in the Russian path it is to encourage the social democrats of all persuasions, and discourage quick economic fixes, especially those in the advocates’ self-interest.

Tax and the Cultural Cringe

Comparing the US and New Zealand tax systems is comparing rotten apples with quality kiwifruit.
Listener: 14 August, 2004.

Keywords: Regulation & Taxation;

Far too much of the New Zealand economic debate is overwhelmed by the colonial cringe, an obsequious respect to overseas economics, with a failure to recognise that New Zealand circumstances are frequently different. Each May, a Business Roundtable press release, dutifully reported in the business pages, announces “Tax Freedom Day”, the day up to which – so it says – everyone is paying taxes to the government and after which all one earns is tax-free. The idea comes from the US right-wing think tank, the Tax Foundation, and is strongly contested in the US as misleading, because it ignores the fact that one also gets benefits from paying those taxes.

The Business Roundtable imitatively lifted the idea, without noticing that because the New Zealand tax system is pay-as-you-earn, one pays taxes all the year. Tell your Business Roundtable employer to stop deducting PAYE from your wages after the day his lobby group announced as Tax Freedom Day or tell your Business Roundtable supplier you don’t have to pay GST on your purchases after that date. Both will think you are crazy – like the idea of Tax Freedom Day.

The Business Roundtable is so slavishly imitative that it has not even noticed that the US tax year starts on January 1, but the New Zealand one starts on April 1. If a NZ Tax Freedom Day made sense, it would be in August not May. Members of the Business Roundtable seem so ignorant about taxation that perhaps they do not pay taxes.

Because of constitutional differences, the US tax experience is even more irrelevant to New Zealand and much of the rest of the world. The US parliament does not have highly disciplined political parties. The New Zealand Government knows that it can enact any tax measure it introduces because it has the votes in Parliament, whereas in the US, there is no such guarantee because each congressman votes independently of party affiliation. In order to get each congressman’s vote for a tax bill, there has to be something in it for her or him. So every US tax bill has special provisions to gather sufficient congressional support: typically, special exemptions for projects, industries and enterprises.

Thus, a particularly key but obstinate congressman may get a special depreciation deal for the mining in his district, tax exemptions for his farmers, and a billion-dollar rort for some corporation – Enron was an example – that contributed to his election campaign fund. The resulting US tax system is erratic and inefficient, much less coherent than even the one we had before 1984 under Robert Muldoon.

In his book Growing Public: Social Spending and Economic Growth Since the Eighteenth Century, Peter Lindert points out that European countries have much more efficient tax gathering systems, so they are able to raise higher taxes to fund a more comprehensive welfare state than the US. On the basis of the evidence, he concludes that their “net social costs of transfers, and the taxes that finance them, are essentially zero. They do not bring the GDP costs that much of the Anglo-American literature has imagined.” He goes on: “High budget democracies show more care in choosing the design of taxes and transfers so as to avoid compromising growth … Broad universalism in taxes and entitlements fosters growth better than the low-budget countries’ preferences for strict means testing and complicated tax compromises.”

New Zealand’s tax system is more like the European ones in terms of coherence, so, if we want to, we can raise more revenue and spend more on education, health, social transfers, the environment, recreation and culture and whatever we think socially desirable, compared to what Americans can.

Comparing the US and New Zealand tax systems is comparing rotten apples with quality kiwifruit. It makes no sense, unless you have a colonial mentality. Not that we should ignore Americans altogether. Lindert is a distinguished US economic historian, who has immersed himself in the data and differences between countries. His book offers numerous insights, with a sensitivity to the differences in circumstances between country and over time. It is not colonial cringe to use overseas research, but it is intellectually challenging to adapt foreign theory and practices to New Zealand conditions.

Sugarcoating

When the international price of cotton and sugar is raised, why should we be pleased?
Listener: 31 July 2004.

Keywords: Globalisation & Trade;

As unlikely as it may seem, cotton and sugar are playing a vital role in New Zealand’s economic prospects. A World Trade Organisation panel has just found in favour of a Brazilian – and others – complaint that the US is subsidising or “dumping” its exports of cotton. The panel concluded that the US action depresses international cotton prices, so other cotton exporters are getting lower than free – or fair – market prices. It rules that the dumping must stop.

The US is appealing the decision, but most observers expect it to lose. It has a record of going to the last court of appeal, and then caving in when it loses there, as it did over its illegal hike in the tariff on our lamb. This enables its trade negotiators to say to their farmers that they did their best, although I suspect the diplomats will be happy to lose in the wider interests of US trade strategy.

The Brazilians have a similar claim against European Union sugar exports. Although the WTO decision has yet to be made, everyone expects the same conclusion: that the EU is dumping its sugar surplus on world markets, depressing prices, and it should desist, too. Ending the dumping will raise international prices of cotton and sugar. Although Third World producers will be better off, New Zealand consumers will have to pay more. Why should we be pleased?

The point is the principle: rich countries in particular are not allowed to subsidise their own producers, and then dump surpluses from overproduction into world markets, depressing the returns of unsubsidised producers. That principle applies to all farm exports, including dairy products. So New Zealand dairy farmers will be better off with the ending of dumping and their gains, spread through the rest of the economy, will be considerably greater than any consumer losses. A rule of thumb is that every dollar we get from higher export prices relative to import prices adds three dollars to national spending in the long run.

The EU as good as conceded that it is going to lose the sugar case, when its Trade Commissioner, Pascal Lamy, announced that the EU will support steps in the Doha Round trade negotiations to eliminate subsiding of exports, providing others do the same. The US, the other big player in the negotiations, welcomed the proposal. Its trade negotiators already support the elimination of dumping. But never forget that – as in the EU – US farmers are divided, since some, such as cotton producers, benefit from the dumping, while others suffer. In contrast, dumping is an unmitigated disaster for New Zealand farmers, because we do not do any ourselves.

The EU is similarly conflicted. Many of its members are tired of subsidising others’ farmers, and especially nervous given that some of the countries that joined last May have large – and largely inefficient – farm sectors. On the other hand, France, a net beneficiary of the EU’s Common Agricultural Policy, protested against Lamy’s announcement. However, the EU has been reforming its agricultural subsidies to align more closely its producer prices with those in the international markets, so the internal consequences of their ending dumping may not be large.

There was a cheer when Lamy made the announcement, because the Doha Round, which aims to reduce trade interventions, seemed to have got stuck over agriculture protection. Both the Europeans and the Americans want a major decision by early August, because of elections later in the year.

Any agreement will only offer a general framework, and there will be much work to be done on details. So when and if success is announced, don’t expect immediate benefits. Even after the final settlement a year and more later, the new policies will phase in. More-over, the EU, US and Japan are unlikely to remove all the barricades defending their domestic food markets from New Zealand (and other) competition – not this time round, anyway. But eliminating dumping into third markets will boost our dairy industry, while products such as fish and timber will get better access and prices, too. The benefits will flow through to all of us, although consumers of cotton and sugar will have to take a small downside.

The Relevance Of GDP

A Report prepared in February 2003.

Keywords: Growth & Innovation; Statistics;

Contents
Introduction
What is GDP?
Comparing GDP Through Time
Comparing GDP Between Countries: Purchasing Power Parity
How Satisfactory is the Adjustment?
Comparisons Through Time
Scaling PPP adjusted GDP
Ranking by GDP
Does GDP Measure Economic Welfare?
Alternative Measures to GDP

Notes

Introduction

GDP is used extensively in economic analysis and in the public economic discourse. More recently a particular version of GDP – per capita GDP measured in international purchasing power parity prices – has been used for international comparisons, and it has been argued that it is the relevant economic goal. Thus the target of ‘the top half of the OECD’ by some target date is to be evaluated by this measure.

This report is more cautious. It will argue that GDP is a part of a comprehensive system of economic analysis which enables systematic consideration of the economy at sectoral and industry level. Hence it is a valuable measure. However, it is inappropriate to use the indicator as an overall measure of the achievement of a society, or as its ultimate goal. For a number of reasons – which the report details – international measures of GDP suffer even further problems. Even so, comparing New Zealand’s per capita GDP measured in international purchasing power parity prices has so merit.

What is GDP?

Statistics New Zealand defines its Gross Domestic Product as ‘the total market value of goods and services produced in New Zealand, after deducting the costs of goods and services utilised in the process of production, but before deducting allowances for the consumption of fixed capital’.

There are three separate ways of looking at GDP. First, it is the aggregate net production of the economy. (The ‘net’ is to avoid double counting of inputs – including imports.) Second, it is the income that the production generates. Third, it is the disposal of the production, usually called ‘expenditure’. In principle each approach offers a different way of measuring GDP, but because all the production is disposed of, and because all the relevant income is generated from the net production, in principle the three measures yield exactly the same total. In practice there is measurement error, and so the actually measured totals can differ significantly (sometimes in percentage terms by more than the annual growth rate) because of measurement difficulties.

Note that the theoretical equality of the three measures only occurs when they are valued in the current prices. When other prices are used, there are theoretical as well as practical differences between the totals of the three measures.

GDP is the most prominent indicator derived from the System of National Accounts (SNA). As such, it is embedded in a comprehensive data base which attempts to characterise the main movements in the economy by statistical measures of income, production and expenditure at the aggregate, sectoral and industry level. Although this is not always evident in the popular discourse, economic analysis sees the various elements of the SNA interacting with each other – behaviourally as well as mathematically – and the GDP as a summary indicator of the interactions.

For many purposes another element of the SNA such as National Income (NI) would be a better aggregate outcome indicator. National Income is GDP less the consumption of fixed capital (depreciation), and reflects the income of the nationals (i.e of New Zealanders) rather than the income generated in New Zealand some of which goes to non-nationals. (NI also includes income New Zealanders earn overseas, which is included in other countries GDPs.) New Zealand National Income is a better measure of the true spending power of New Zealanders, that is (according to the definition proposed by John Hicks) the maximum amount they can spend and still have the same stock of assets at the end. It is still subject to the most of major criticisms of the inadequacy of GDP as a welfare indicator (below).[1]

GDP’s advantage is that it better reflects the underlying production basis on which the SNA is based, while the adjustments to derive NI are both conceptually problematic and subject to a larger error.

Comparing GDP Through Time

Because GDP is measured in market prices, and those prices change – especially given the tendency of the prices to generally rise (inflation) – a comparison of the ‘nominal’ GDP over time is not very useful. To facilitate a better comparison, the GDP at different points in time is valued in the same set of prices, usually the prices of the first year of the series.[2] This repriced GDP is sometimes called ‘GDP in constant prices’, or ‘real GDP’ (as opposed to nominal GDP), or ‘volume GDP’ (as opposed to value GDP). The ‘constant price’ name is the most technically correct, but a little clumsy. ‘Volume GDP’ is probably a better convenient term than ‘real GDP’, since the latter may imply to some that there is some GDP which is unreal.[3]

The repricing raises four problems, each of which also apply, to some (greater)degree, when international GDP comparisons are made.

First, not every item can be individually priced. One procedure is to obtain representative prices for some of the goods and services in a production or expenditure group, and to calculate a weighted increase of those prices, using that to deflate the change in the value of the production or expenditure. (It may be noted that international comparisons use far fewer commodities priced than national consumer price indexes.)

Second, new products arise and the quality of products change over time. There are a number of ways which statisticians allow for this, but ultimately one is left with the doubt that data comparisons through time are problematic because in the short run they dont properly allow for technology changes and in the long run they dont properly allow for new products.[4]

Third, some products cannot be priced as an output and have to be priced on an input basis. The public sector services are valued by the sum of their inputs (mainly labour). Where that happens, the procedure does not systematically allow for productivity changes although some countries make add hoc adjustments for believed changes in (labour) productivity. Additional capital goods (investment) are also, in effect, valued as inputs (so that an inefficient construction makes a higher contribution to GDP than a more efficient one which does the same job).

Fourth, while nominal GDP measured on the production side is exactly theoretically equal to nominal GDP measured on the expenditure side, the volume GDP measured from production and expenditure sides need not be theoretically equal. The divergence arises because of the impact of changes in relative prices between exports and imports (the terms of trade). Suppose export prices fall in a year relative to import prices, while the volume of exports remains exactly the same, and that all other prices remain the same. The constant-price production side estimate will not change between the two years. However there will be less volume imports (since the exports purchase less of them), less expenditure, so the constant-price expenditure side estimate will fall. Because New Zealand has experienced substantial terms of trades shifts, the distinction was important when wages were indexed to productivity changes. The expenditure side estimate of GDP was then called ‘effective GDP’, now defined in the SNA as ‘Real Gross Domestic Income’ (RGDI).

Comparing GDP Between Countries: Purchasing Power Parity

In principle the comparison between countries is exactly the same as the comparison over time: that is the same set of prices are applied to the production in each country.

Because the prices in different countries involve different currencies, in effect each product has its own exchange rate. Suppose the currency used for all product valuations was the international standard unit (ISU). Then for every product there would be a local currency price and an ISU price, and each ratio would be an exchange rate for each product. These exchange rates – or as they are known purchasing power parities (PPPs) – vary by product. For instance in 1998, the comparative price level most expensive New Zealand SNA group (Alcoholic Beverage, Tobacco and Narcotics) was 74 percent higher than the least expensive (Education).[5]

Before there was any of the detailed price comparisons (which exist for many, but not all, countries) the only available exchange rate was that between the internationally traded currencies. Converting GDP with the currency exchange rate was obviously wrong because changes in the exchange rates did not reflect underlying changes in prices.[6]

A textbook illustration of the notion of purchasing power parity is the McDonalds hamburger rate, which the London Economist publishes (it being easy for journalists to collect). The standard McDonalds hamburger has exactly the same content wherever it is sold. The Economist argues price for the hamburger reflects the average level of prices in the economy. But economies produce many more products than hamburgers, and the relativities between their prices and the hamburger is not constant, not least because case some of the inputs in a hamburger are subject to protection and subsidies – notably beef. Regrettably the McDonald’s exchange rate is given far more prominence than is justified.[7]

At the simplest level one might apply the prices of one country (as Australia) to another (New Zealand). The resulting measure might suggest the ‘Australian’ GDP was x percent greater than the ‘New Zealand’ GDP. Reversing the exercise, by applying ‘New Zealand’ prices to ‘Australian’ production might suggest that ‘Australian’ GDP was now y percent greater than the ‘New Zealand’ GDP. As a general rule ‘x’ will not equal ‘y’ so that different price purchasing power parity regimes give different relativities. This is no different in principle to what happens in price comparisons over different years (or the difference between the Paasche and Laspeyre price indexes). However the inter-country differences tend to be larger than the inter-time differences. Moreover, year data can be ordered through time. Country comparisons have no such general ordering, and the inclusion of a third country adds to the paradoxes. A different choice of an average set of international prices might lead to different relativities.

How Satisfactory is the Adjustment?

Deriving the international average prices is nor easy. There are technical answers, but they add a degree of error in that different answers may result in slightly different relativity.

There are three recognised weaknesses in the current procedures, which are also evident in the over-time comparisons, but to a lesser degree.
(1) It is difficult to get representative prices across economies. The McDonalds illustration makes it look misleadingly easy, but consider the complications of getting a price for something as basic as bread for a number of different countries given the variation in the style of breads. Housing is particularly difficult.
(2) The reliance on input measures for evaluating the public sector. In effect public sector workers with the same job specifications and qualifications are assumed to have the same productivity in all countries, an assumption which is clearly not true in the private sector.
(3) International comparisons of the price of capital investment products, are difficult.[8]

Recently, a further problem has been identified, although thus far the investigation has been preliminary. Products are priced differently depending on whether they are consumed or exported. Exports are priced at internationally traded prices while consumption is priced at (average) domestic traded prices. In a free-trade world the two would be the same (transport and distribution margins aside). However where there is protection there may be a substantial difference between the (average) export price and the (average) domestic price, and the PPP adjusted GDPs on the production and expenditure side will differ. In particular, the GDP of an economy whose exports face protection will be higher measured by the products it produces (the ‘production side’ estimate) than by the disposal of the products (the ‘expenditure side’ estimate). Conversely, an economy which protects its domestic industry but imports some of the protected product will have a higher expenditure side PPP.

Only the PPP adjusted expenditure side GDP is estimated. The implication is that those countries whose exports suffer strong discrimination will appear (relatively) lower than had the estimate been done on the production side. The exact meanings and implications are yet to be explored. It may be that the so-called PPP-adjusted GDP is more comparable with a PPP-RGDPI, that it is gives a measure of spending power rather than production.

There is a need to quantify the effect. The divergence for most OECD countries is likely to be small but in New Zealand’s case the difference may be in the order of 10 percent because of the high proportion of discriminated-against exports in GDP, and the high levels of discrimination. If so, half the gap between New Zealand’s PPP adjusted GDP and the mean may be explained by protection against New Zealand’s exports.

More generally, estimates of sectoral productivity based on the production side (the only practical way of doing this) will not sum to aggregate productivity based on PPP adjusted GDP derived from the expenditure side.

Comparisons Through Time

In principle the growth of PPP adjusted GDP ought to confirm to the growth of GDP based on the constant price series. As Table 1 suggests, there is a mismatch between the 1990 and 1998 figures.[9] Some 16 of the 23 economies experience an annual difference between the two estimates greater than 0.3%. Errors of this magnitude in a year tend to cause comment. Yet this was the average error for 8 years.

The implications could be some or all of:
(1) The 1990 PPP adjustments were wrong;
(2) The 1998 PPP adjustments were wrong;
(3) The constant price series are wrong;
(4) The expenditure side GDP on which the PPP adjusted series are estimated, has a different growth record to the production GDP figures on which the constant price figures are usually based;
(5) Revisions to methodology are important (as they certainly were between 1985 and 1990).
(6) It may reflect the ambiguity between GDP and RGDI. (When I used the RGDI growth rate for NZ instead of the GDP one the error difference was eliminated. However some of the country errors seem far larger than could be explained by a terms of trade effect.)

PPP adjusted GDPs are estimated at three year intervals, the previous rounds being 1980, 1985, 1990, 1993, 1996, and 1999. The next, due for release next year is for 2002. Other years may be interpolated or extrapolated using volume GDP growth rates. However this results of this section caution could be misleading. Additionally, the GDP (and population) data for individual years takes a little time to settle down because of revisions as new information comes in, so that extrapolation is more hazardous.

Scaling PPP adjusted GDP

Countries with bigger populations tend to have bigger GDPs, so it is usual to compare economies by per capita GDP. (Whether there should be some adjustment for the age distribution – children usually consume less than adults – is rarely considered.)

More recently there has been some attention to comparing the economies by labour force and by hours work. The resulting rankings are shown in Table 2. While the Netherlands is only 107 percent of the OECD average (of 27 economies – hourly data was not available for three OECD countries.) on a per capita basis, it is 145 percent on a per hour basis.[10]

Thus the US is behind Netherlands, Belgium, Norway, Italy and Ireland on a per hour basis.[11] Apparently part of US economic strength arises from Americans working longer hours. (The ‘apparently’ is necessary, because while the hours worked data comes from the OECD, it is not clear how well the individual countries are comparable and verified.)

New Zealanders work slightly more hours per capita than the OECD average, and so their average hourly productivity is slightly lower than the per capita one, measurement problems aside. The figure does not include commuting hours. If New Zealanders commuted an hour a day less than the OECD average, hourly productivity including commuting would be closer to 80 percent of the average.

More generally, adjusting for hours work (together with commuting hours were that possible) illustrates not only how fragile the relativities are, but that GDP by itself is inadequate insofar as it ignores the amount of accompanying leisure.

Ranking by GDP

The public rhetoric focuses upon New Zealand’s ranking and defines a goal in terms of ranking, rather as if it is a race. As in the Infometrics report prepared for NZTE, economists tend to work with the ratio of scaled GDPs, as in the second and fourth columns of Table 2, in contrast to the third and fifth columns. The technical reason is that a cardinal measure (such as a ratio) is far easier to work with than an ordinal measure (such as a ranking). In any case, there is a loss of information from reducing a cardinal to an ordinal measure, for ordinal measure (rankings) can be derived from cardinal measures (the ratio) but not the reverse.

Rankings can be very misleading. New Zealand lost only one place (to Ireland) between 1985 and 1999 on per capita GDP, but the relativity to average OECD fell by about 15 percent. On the other hand in the 1970s when New Zealand was growing as fast as the OECD, a number of countries growing fractionally faster passed it. There were few economies just behind New Zealand in 1985 and a lot in 1975. In racing parlance, in 1985 the economy could slow down to a walk but there was nobody near enough to pass it, whereas in 1975 New Zealand was catching up with the front runners, but others were catching up faster. That this can be misleading is evident from the Treasury growth studies which use rankings, and fail to pay sufficient attention to the poor performance in the late 1980s and early 1990s, because the ranking had not changed much.

Rankings hide bunching. The table shows five countries in the range 101 to 107 percent of the OECD average, all within measurement error of 104 percent. Slight errors may change rankings. In a recent paper The PPP Programme and the Uses of PPPs, the head of the program, Paul Schreyer cautioned that a 2 percent difference was within measurement error. Rankings give no indication of measurement error.

A further complication is that new member economies are being added to the OECD. Most are at the poorer end which means the OECD median and the mean are usually lower following the addition of new members (which also destabilises the data in past studies, and the public rhetoric).

In summary, the rankings are a poor way of characterising the situation New Zealand is in, has been in, and can be in. Relativities are better, but even they change as additional countries are added. Because of measurement errors, the relativities and rankings tend to jump around from data base to revised data base.

Does GDP Measure Economic Welfare?

The short answer to the question of whether GDP (or NI) is a good measure of economic welfare is that it is not. When the measure was systematically derived in the 1930s and 1940s, welfare was not a focus. The concern was with practical issues of how to determine employment and how to ‘pay for the war’. There is a theory which might be used to conclude that NI is a measure of welfare but it assumes the utilitarian theory that human welfare only increases by the increase in the goods and services transacted in the market.

While on occasions commentators – not always well versed in economics or the relevant theory – point out the inadequacies of GDP as a welfare measure, economists have long known of its deficiencies. In particular the measure omits those things which occur outside the market including most human interactions (including, has we have just seen, leisure), the interactions with the environment, and economic activity which occurs outside the market (such as most housework).[12] Not only are these probably more important, but it sometimes happens that GDP rises at the expense of the omissions.[13] GDP, which is typically measured in a short period of a year or a quarter is not an indicator of sustainability.[14] Much market activity is an input rather than an output in its own right. Examples include military spending, spending on crime justice and on health services, and the elimination of pollution. In each case it is possible to envisage a world where the spending was unnecessary and the nation was better off with a lower GDP: no military threat, without crime, without various health problems, and without pollution.

A further weakness is that GDP ignores the distribution of spending power (income). An economy with a highly unequal distribution of income may have the same GDP as one with a more egalitarian distribution. Yet we may want to judge the two to be quite different in welfare terms. Using GDP as a measure of welfare rests on so-called ‘Hume’s law’ that a dollar is a dollar is a dollar, where a dollar has the same value to a rich person as to a poor one.[15]

Awareness of these deficiencies has not led to their resolution. There have been various attempts to extend GDP to a wider measure, but typically they have proved neither compelling or robust. Among the difficulties have been how to provide ‘market’ prices for activities and transactions which do not occur in the market. Some efforts have also frequently lacked an understanding of the SNA framework out of which GDP is derived.

A recent development raises the even more serious possibility that in rich countries there is no indicator of material output which corelates well with human welfare. The utilitarian assumption that more material goods and services are associated with greater welfare and therefore GDP (or augmented GDP) is a measure of welfare, is an assumption, underpinned by little robust evidence utilising other independent assessments of welfare. Data reporting self-assessed happiness
– does not correlate with growth in GDP overtime (in fact the happiness level in countries where there is tracking remains constant despite rising per capita GDP);
– it correlates only weakly with relative income within countries (for instance marital status is a far stronger indicator of happiness than income);
– among the richest countries per capita GDP does not correlate with average happiness (New Zealand is third equal with the US, despite them being very differently ranked by GDP).

This last cross-national result suggests a possible interpretation. There is a correlation between GDP per capita and reported happiness for those countries with per capita GDPs lower than about 70 percent of New Zealand’s (although other variables are relevant too). This suggests that additional material product may contribute significantly to the welfare of people in poorer economies but that it is an asymptotic and other factors may be important for richer ones.

Alternative Measures to GDP

While researchers may want to explore alternatives to GDP as a measure of welfare, they need to pursue the same rigorous tests as those indicated for GDP. A measure needs to be a part of a comprehensive theoretical framework, which is practically useful, and has demonstrated the usefulness (i.e. been validated). One-off estimates are of little use: the need is for long run time series and cross national comparisons. No other measures meet these criteria.

Net Economic Welfare and Other Extensions

In 1972 two Yale economists, William Nordhaus and James Tobin, proposed a Measure of Economic Welfare (MEW) (now better known as ‘Net Economic Welfare’ (NEW)) in which they began with National Income from which they added the value of leisure time and the underground economy (including under-the-table services such as babysitting, but excluding illegal activities) and deducted environmental damages, the costs of education and health expenses which they judged ‘defensive’, and expenditure on personal security, police services, sanitation services, road maintenance, and the military. The resulting measure proved to have been growing steadily, but more slowly, than NI since 1929 in the US.

This triggered an plethora of associated measures. A popular one is the ‘Genuine Progress Index’ (GPI) proposed in 1995 which made many further adjustments, some of which involve judgements which experts might consider little more than opinions. The GPI for the US only goes back to 1950, but suggests an actual deterioration in recent decades.

However there is little agreement, no internationally comparable data, and no data series for New Zealand, for these new measures. So whatever their merits – they provide a useful base for a discussion of the value of GDP as an indicator of welfare – they are of little practical use.

The most promising development is that in 1993 the SNA set out a procedure for subsidiary tables which are slowly being developed on such activities as the environment, resources and housework, and which may ultimately lead to more general measure of sustainable economic activity, including non-market activity. But until these developments are completed – and even then they will address only some of the defects of GDP – the only measure that seems to meet the practical requirements of availability and rigour is GDP itself, although its use is limited by the caveats of its relevance to welfare discussed above.

Composite Indexes such as the Global Competitiveness Index

There is a practice of collecting together a number of indexes which are loosely related to economic performance and aggregating them. Into a composite index. Perhaps the best know of these is the Global Competitiveness Index, published by the Swiss-based World Economic Forum. Like the McDonalds PPP index, such composites are seized upon by journalists eager for ‘news’. The intellectual underpinnings are less compelling. The sub-indexes from which they are derived tend to be what is available and which suit the opinions of the index constructors, and the weightings of the components tend to be crude. Sometimes it is not even clear whether the variable should be positive or negative.[16]

Typically these indexes are not statistically validated, the opinions of the index constructors being the only justification that the index reflects some economic or social reality. There is no study which shows that the Global Competitiveness Index is usefully associated with economic growth. Even were there one, it’s status would be an input measure, not a(n output) measure of actual performance.

Human Development Index

The Human Development Index (HDI) has been proposed by the United Nations Development Agency, following a long debate in which economist Amartya Sen played a key role. It combines GDP per capita (PPP adjusted) with measures of educational achievement literacy and longevity, following Sen’s notion of the key notion of ‘capability’ which refers to the alternative functionings (‘life choices’) a person might have which indicate the freedom of choice a person has over their life. Material consumption is only a part of that totality, so health and education measures are included.

There are HDI tabulations for international comparisons, which discriminate among the poorer countries and sometimes dramatically change the placing of countries – most famously the Indian State of Karalla which is very poor but has world class longevity and literacy. However the measure is not very useful for rich countries, which tend to attain the maximum levels on each of the indicator the sub-components and so bunch together. Even so, the approach might be extended for them by incorporating measures of sustainability, quality of life and leisure. This has yet to be done.

Full Income

A useful measure, pioneered in Australia, has been ‘Full Income’ in which market income is adjusted for leisure and for the economic value of household assets (such as an owned home, consumer durables, and cars). However this measure is largely used to assess individual households rather than to assess aggregate welfare.[17]

An Index of Family Wealth

A recent proposal has been to use an ‘Index of Family Wealth’ as an indicator of welfare. [18] The indicator is rather unconvincing since it is based on a collection of some household items of families with 15 year old children, so it is neither comprehensive in coverage nor of the population. In any case it is a measure of household asset possession (ignoring financial wealth and debt), not of material product: it is a stock not a flow.

There been no attempt to validate the measure as relevant to welfare nor to fit it into a comprehensive theoretical framework. Another difficulty, evident in recent work by the Ministry of Social Development’s deprivation index, is that while a lack of items may be evidence of deprivation, at the other end of the scale there is a heterogeneity of possessions indicating high welfare. For instance some rich households may have a weekend bach, others may instead have a boat, and yet others neither but they may go regularly on overseas trips.

Does the Pursuit of GDP Undermine Wider Goals?

Much of the criticism of GDP as a measure of welfare is based upon an unease that its pursuit undermines wider social goals. There are some justified sources of such unease. At times, and in places even today, GDP (or perhaps just the unregulated market) growth has resulted in environmental degradation, increasing income inequality, plus other social ills such as rising crime. But while GDP growth has been associated with such detriments in the past and in places, in other times and places it has been associated with cleaning up the environment, less inequality, and reducing crime.

The unease with GDP is reinforced by the advocation of policies which are justified by the pursuit of higher GDP and yet which appear to damage other social goals. There is not the space to go through every argument and every instance, but a current New Zealand debate is revealing.

For various reasons every government intervenes, by spending and taxation, to change the composition of GDP. There is a theory which says that such interventions will reduce GDP (or, more tenuously, the growth of GDP). There is also an argument that such interventions may enhance GDP (or its growth). Advocates of the first argument have attempted to collect evidence to support their case (the same tests are also implicitly testing the second argument). Despite their persistence and ingenuity, to the scientific eye the advocates have quite failed to provide sound evidence.

I was surprised by this failure. While there may be beneficial effects on GDP growth from government spending, these tend to be long term, whereas the theory would predict the effects of taxation would be reasonably quick. Given the lack of convincing empirical evidence one concludes that any effect is so small as to be unmeasurable, and may be ignored within reasonable bounds.

But suppose there had been evidence that government interventions had depressed GDP. The interventions may still be justified if the differently composed – but lower – GDP was socially superior. It is not implausible that, given an effective and democratic political process, that the government interventions shift the economy in a more socially superior direction.

In fact nobody is a total supporter of GDP per capita as the ultimate social target. A ready means of lifting New Zealand into the top half of the GDP stakes would be to execute everyone over the age of 65. (Executing children too would take GDP per capita near Luxembourg levels.) A nation has higher goals than GDP per capita.

Of course the government should assess the effectiveness of its interventions, and ensure the burden of taxation is as light as is possible for given social goals, within those reasonable bounds. The evidence seems to be that New Zealand is comfortably inside the range, of, say, the tax burden or spending ratio to GDP.

Has GDP any Relevance to Welfare?

Given the above discussion has GDP any relevance to national objectives? The short answer is that a growth in GDP is an indicator of the ability of the community to increase its market production. This increase may result in greater community welfare insofar as
– it creates jobs for those who would be otherwise employed;
– increases Sen’s ‘capability’, indicating the freedom of choice a person has over their life. (Important instances of such enhancement could arise from spending on education and health, and the provision of community, cultural and recreational facilities);
– the resulting composition of GDP reflects national values. (In New Zealand’s case this would include more (private and public) spending on health services, education, on cultural and recreational services, and on environmental protection and enhancement.)

On the other hand, care has to be taken to ensure GDP growth does not result in social bads such as crime and social dislocation, and pollution and environmental destruction.

This approach s integral to the government’s ‘Growth and Innovation Framework’ and to its ‘Sustainable Development Strategy’.

Using GDP

The existence of GDP (or one of its associated measures such as NI) as a measure of economic performance is largely fait de mieux, there being no alternative which is as rigorously and comprehensively constructed, available over long periods, and for many countries. Perhaps one day there will be other measures – such as New Economic Welfare – which will have conceptual merits over GDP and which will be as readily available in comprehensive rigorous comparative data bases.

However there are positive aspects of the SNA cluster of measures (of which GDP is the most prominent) which is useful given a remit increasing the capacity of the New Zealand economy to produce in order for the nation to pursue its wider goals. That GDP is imbedded in an system of national accounts enhances its usefulness for those with concerns of sectors, exports and productivity.

However, GDP is not the ultimate national goal. The concerns captured by GDP are but one component which contributes to it. Sometimes other considerations may mean that a policy will depress GDP or inhibit its growth. It may be appropriate for agencies with primarily an economic remit, to draw the government’s attention to any depressing effects of the policy. But ultimately they will accept that in the government’s judgement the resulting composition of GDP may be socially superior. (Note, however, there is little evidence that the overall impact of interventions has been deleterious on GDP, so the effect of any particular one may not be great.)

Given the Government’s Growth and Innovation Framework specifically embraces the open economy – it will want to think about GDP and GDP growth in an international context. The best available readily measure would New Zealand’s PPP adjusted per capita GDP relative to some group of countries average (rather than the ranking between countries). The natural group of countries for comparison would be the OECD, although future additions to membership make comparisons over time complicated.

Moreover, as we have seen, PPP adjusted per capita GDP suffers from various measurement defects, including it is published for only every third year with a long publication lag (of almost three years). Given these difficulties what aggregate measure might we choose to assess the economic performance of the economy?

Choosing a Measure of Economic Performance

The first principle is that the measure should be a relativity not a ranking, that is New Zealand should be evaluated against some average performance of a group of countries. .

Given the need is for a robust and internationally accepted economic measure there is little available other than GDP measured in PPP prices. Where this is not immediately available it can be updated from the latest benchmark year by using volume GDP growth estimates. Ideally, and hopefully in the next few years practically, other related measures from the SNA system will become available. The most useful from the suite might be National Income measured in PPP prices. When a choice is offered between GDP on a production basis and GDP on an expenditure basis, it is likely that more weight should be given to the former, because of New Zealand’s lack of control over its terms of trade and the practice of international protection.

The current practice is to scale the GDP measure by population. It is recommended that this practice be continued until there are reliable estimates of hours worked. There is probably little merit in using the interim step of scaling by workers, because of differences in the treatment of part and full time workers.

What group of countries should the performance measure compare itself with? Here are some choices, noting that a major limitation on choice is that not all countries are included in the OECD exercise. The possible combinations are enormous, so only some obvious choices.

Countries

1. All the countries for which the OECD provides statistics. This consists of the 30 OECD countries, 8 candidate EU countries who may soon join the OECD, and 5 other countries Croatia, Israel, Macedonia, the Russian Federation and the Ukraine. In my view this group is too diverse, and in any case a number of them have standards of living and economic structures which are rather different from New Zealand’s.

2. All OECD countries. The difficulty here is that more countries are likely to be joining the OECD soon, so the group is not stable.

3. Pacific countries. This is a grouping which the PPP estimation process groups together: Australia, Canada, Israel, Japan, Korea, Mexico, New Zealand, the United States. (Israel is for convenience.)

4. A group of countries which are small, high income, and geographically isolated from the three main economic engines of the United States, the European core, and Japan. they might be Australia, Finland, Iceland, Ireland, Israel, New Zealand, Norway and possibly Denmark, Greece, and/or Portugal. The notion here is that size and isolation are two particular problems for New Zealand.

5. Australia, by itself, although comparing with a single country is likely to generate unnecessary rivalries and inappropriate comparisons of policies.

6. High middle income countries. The OECD partitions its 43 into three groups, and partitions again the middle group of countries into high middle income and low middle income country. New Zealand belongs to the later, which consists of 14 countries with Israel, Cyprus, New Zealand, Spain, Portugal, and Greece in order, at the top. The high middle country group (in order) is Iceland, Canada, Netherlands, Ireland, Austria, Japan, Belgium, Germany, Australia Sweden, Italy, United Kingdom. Finland and France, As the accompanying diagram shows, the division is not entirely arbitrary.

The challenge of New Zealand rejoining the High Middle Income Group would involve it growing about 1 percent p.a. faster in GDP per capita terms for a decade (on the current measure). Ultimately, that is probably the goal that New Zealand really seeks, although the path to the goal can be articulated in various ways.

Notes
[1] Note that NI (and, more generally, the National Accounts), cover only market assets, and do not allow for depletion of natural and environmental resources.
[2] More recently, the succeeding year GDP is valued in the prices of the preceding year. The longer series is constructed by chaining linking the overlapping year increases.
[3] The problem of measuring inventory change is not included here, because the inventory valuation adjustment issue which arises because prices change with the period of measurement, applies to nominal estimates also.
[4] In principle price indexes ought to be able to answer questions like: What amount of income in 1903 would enable a person to be on the same material standard of living as, say, the average wage in 2003. Because of the many new products over the hundred years it is difficult to even think about how to answer this.
[5] Not described here is the complicated system of weighting prices between countries.
[6] For instance between July 2001 and December 2003 there has been a 44 percent rise in the euro relative to the dollar. Yet it would be nonsense to infer there had been a similar change in the relative GDPs. If a country devalues by 19.45 percent, say, as New Zealand did in 1967, production did not fall overnight by 19.45 percent.
[7] The Economist has recently introduced a ‘Tall Latte’ PPP based on its price in Starbucks in 19 countries. The correlation coefficient between Starbucks latte and McDonald hamburgers was .79, suggesting either measure has some relationship with a true PPP but probably not a perfect one.
[8] For the 1985 PPP estimates, New Zealand was asked to provide a construction price for a two-up/two-down brick terraced house, while the price for the equivalent standard New Zealand bungalow was not requested. Because New Zealand builders were unfamiliar with such terraced houses their price was well out of line with typical construction prices in New Zealand. In the 1985 PPP adjusted GDP data for New Zealand, the volume of capital formation appears low relative to the volume of consumption. This instance has since been addressed, but it cannot be entirely avoided.
[9] The table is based on the 1990 and 1998 tabulations. Only 24 countries were reported in 1990. Germany was omitted because of the change in boundaries over the period. It is assumed that the average growth rates for the 23 are correct, since PPP adjusted data only gives relative growth rates.
[10] However, considerable caution is necessary in the use of the hour figures. There does not seem a lot of confidence that they are accurate/comparable.
[11] The exceptionally higher placing of Luxembourg probably reflect its rather special population (just as major cities tend to have higher per capita GDP than the rest of the economy) together with many of its workers commute from neighbouring countries. Its GNP relativity would be lower.
[12] A practical, rather than conceptual, omission is the unmeasured parts of the gray and black economies. We do not know their extent – attempts to measure it are unconvincing academic exercises – nor the extent the under-measurement differs from economy to economy or over time.
[13] When home childcare is replaced by paid childcare, GDP increases, even though there may be no effective change in total (market and non-market) economic activity.
[14] Resource depletion and environmental pollution may be a part of ‘Gross’ Domestic Product, but they are not deducted when ‘Net’ Income is derived, despite the activity being as unsustainable as capital depreciation.
[15] David Hume would be appalled to have his name associated with this as a welfare principle.
[16] A famous case, albeit from some years back, was a dispute as to whether the divorce rate was a positive in a national welfare index, indicative of a tolerant liberal society, or a negative indicative of marriage instability. (It is not difficult to see how the opinions of the index constructor would determine the way the divorce rate would be included.)
[17] Suzie Carson and I, using the New Zealand Household Survey data base, added to financial income an imputation for owner-occupied housing and found this ‘fuller income’ a better predictor of the expenditure items we were investigating. This suggests that ‘fuller income’ may be more relevant for household behaviour and welfare.
[18] It should be noted the article advocating the Index of Family Wealth makes some unfounded criticisms of the PPP measure which suggests the writer is not familiar with its methodology:
“The studies use rather outdated estimates of living costs. Other technical issues (such as the appropriateness of the basket of goods used in the measure) also raise concerns that PPP figures are not always reliable for making cross-country comparisons.”
The studies do not use ‘outdated estimates’: the 1998 estimates use 1998 prices. The concept of ‘living costs’ is not used by statistician and it is not clear what it means. What is meant by ‘the appropriateness of the basket of goods’ is also unclear, since the PPP measure covers all goods and services.

Various tables from the original report are not included

Go to top